Leontief utilities: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
m Cleaned up using AutoEd
Add references
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Multiple issues|
{{refimprove|date=August 2014}}
}}

In [[economics]] and [[consumer theory]], a '''Leontief utility function''' is a function of the form:
In [[economics]] and [[consumer theory]], a '''Leontief utility function''' is a function of the form:


Line 27: Line 23:
== Solving for Walrasian–Marshallian demand ==
== Solving for Walrasian–Marshallian demand ==
Solving for [[Marshallian demand|Walrasian–Marshallian demand]] is a simple affair with utility functions representing Leontief preferences.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://dirkbergemann.commons.yale.edu/files/lecture_notes-vp-db.pdf|title=Intermediate Micro Lecture Notes|last=|first=|date=21 October 2013|work=Yale University|accessdate=21 October 2013}}</ref> One need only set equal the terms of the min function and solve then w.r.t the income constraint [Income = (p1)*(x1)+ … + (pn)(xn)]
Solving for [[Marshallian demand|Walrasian–Marshallian demand]] is a simple affair with utility functions representing Leontief preferences.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://dirkbergemann.commons.yale.edu/files/lecture_notes-vp-db.pdf|title=Intermediate Micro Lecture Notes|last=|first=|date=21 October 2013|work=Yale University|accessdate=21 October 2013}}</ref> One need only set equal the terms of the min function and solve then w.r.t the income constraint [Income = (p1)*(x1)+ … + (pn)(xn)]

== Competitive equilibrium ==
Since Leontief utilities are not strictly convex, they do not satisfy the requirements of the [[Arrow–Debreu model]] for existence of a [[competitive equilibrium]]. Indeed, a Leontief economy is not guaranteed to have a [[competitive equilibrium]]. There are restricted families of Leontief economies that do have a competitive equilibrium.

There is a [[Reduction (complexity)|reduction]] from the problem of finding a [[Nash equilibrium]] in a two-player game to the problem of finding a competitive equilibrium in a Leontief economy.<ref name=co2006>{{Cite conference|doi=10.1145/1109557.1109629}}</ref> This has several implications:
* It is [[NP-hard]] to say whether a particular family of Leontief exchange economies, that is guaranteed to have at least one equilibrium, has more than one equilibrium.
* It is [[NP-hard]] to decide whether a Leontief economy has an equilibrium.

On the other hand, there are algorithms for finding an approximate equilibrium for some special Leontief economies.<ref name=co2006/><ref name=co2004>{{Cite conference|doi=10.1007/978-3-540-27836-8_33}}</ref>


== References ==
== References ==
Line 32: Line 37:


[[Category:Utility function types]]
[[Category:Utility function types]]


{{econ-theory-stub}}

Revision as of 16:06, 2 December 2015

In economics and consumer theory, a Leontief utility function is a function of the form:

.

where:

  • is the number of different goods in the economy.
  • (for ) is the amount of good in the bundle..
  • (for ) is the weight of good for the consumer.

This form of utility function was first conceptualized by Wassily Leontief.

Examples

Leontief utility functions represent complementary goods. For example:

  • Suppose is the number of left shoes and the number of right shoes. A consumer can only use pairs of shoes. Hence, his utility is .
  • In a cloud computing environment, there is a large server that runs many different tasks. Suppose a certain type of a task requires 2 CPUs, 3 gigabytes of memory and 4 gigabytes of disk-space to complete. The utility of the user is equal to the number of completed tasks. Hence, it can be represented by: .

Properties

A consumer with a linear utility function has the following properties:

  • The preferences are weakly monotone but not strictly monotone: having a larger quantity of a single good does not increase utility, but having a larger quantity of all goods does.
  • The preferences are weakly convex, but not strictly convex: a mix of two equivalent bundles may be either equivalent to or better than the original bundles.
  • The indifference curves are L-shaped and their corners are determined by the weights. E.g, for the function , the corners of the indifferent curves are at where .

Solving for Walrasian–Marshallian demand

Solving for Walrasian–Marshallian demand is a simple affair with utility functions representing Leontief preferences.[1] One need only set equal the terms of the min function and solve then w.r.t the income constraint [Income = (p1)*(x1)+ … + (pn)(xn)]

Competitive equilibrium

Since Leontief utilities are not strictly convex, they do not satisfy the requirements of the Arrow–Debreu model for existence of a competitive equilibrium. Indeed, a Leontief economy is not guaranteed to have a competitive equilibrium. There are restricted families of Leontief economies that do have a competitive equilibrium.

There is a reduction from the problem of finding a Nash equilibrium in a two-player game to the problem of finding a competitive equilibrium in a Leontief economy.[2] This has several implications:

  • It is NP-hard to say whether a particular family of Leontief exchange economies, that is guaranteed to have at least one equilibrium, has more than one equilibrium.
  • It is NP-hard to decide whether a Leontief economy has an equilibrium.

On the other hand, there are algorithms for finding an approximate equilibrium for some special Leontief economies.[2][3]

References

  1. ^ "Intermediate Micro Lecture Notes" (PDF). Yale University. 21 October 2013. Retrieved 21 October 2013.
  2. ^ a b . doi:10.1145/1109557.1109629. {{cite conference}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)
  3. ^ . doi:10.1007/978-3-540-27836-8_33. {{cite conference}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)