Jump to content

Equation of exchange

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by 2601:8c4:4300:18b0:a467:ffaf:96a4:e3fc (talk) at 20:26, 29 May 2022 (Fix an error). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

In monetary economics, the equation of exchange is the relation:

where, for a given period,

is the total money supply in circulation on average in an economy.
is the velocity of money, that is the average frequency with which a unit of money is spent.
is the price level.
is an index of real expenditures (on newly produced goods and services).

Thus PQ is the level of nominal expenditures. This equation is a rearrangement of the definition of velocity: V = PQ / M. As such, without the introduction of any assumptions, it is a tautology. The quantity theory of money adds assumptions about the money supply, the price level, and the effect of interest rates on velocity to create a theory about the causes of inflation and the effects of monetary policy.

In earlier analysis before the wide availability of the national income and product accounts, the equation of exchange was more frequently expressed in transactions form:

where

is the transactions velocity of money, that is the average frequency across all transactions with which a unit of money is spent (including not just expenditures on newly produced goods and services, but also purchases of used goods, financial transactions involving money, etc.).
is an index of the real value of aggregate transactions.

Foundation

The foundation of the equation of exchange is the more complex relation:

where:

and are the respective price and quantity of the i-th transaction.
is a row vector of the .
is a column vector of the .

The equation:

is based upon the presumption of the classical dichotomy — that there is a relatively clean distinction between overall increases or decreases in prices and underlying, “real” economic variables — and that this distinction may be captured in terms of price indices, so that inflationary or deflationary components of p may be extracted as the multiplier P, which is the aggregate price level:

where is a row vector of relative prices; and likewise for

In 2008 economist Andrew Naganoff (Template:Lang-ru) proposed an integral form of the equation of exchange, where on the left side of the equation is under the integral sign, and on the right side is a sum from i=1 to . Generally, could be infinite. There are two variants of this formula:

=

and

The simplest cases for the dissipative scaling factors and are: , .

Also, can be determined by the methods of the fuzzy sets.

If liquidity function , then, by the mean value theorem:

=

Naganoff's formula is used to describe in details the processes of inflation and deflation, Internet trading and cryptocurrencies.

Applications

Quantity theory of money

The quantity theory of money is most often expressed and explained in mainstream economics by reference to the equation of exchange. For example, a rudimentary theory could begin with the rearrangement

If and were constant or growing at the same fixed rate as each other, then:

and thus

where

is time.

That is to say that, if and were constant or growing at equal fixed rates, then the inflation rate would exactly equal the growth rate of the money supply.

An opponent of the quantity theory would not be bound to reject the equation of exchange, but could instead postulate offsetting responses (direct or indirect) of or of to .

Money demand

Economists Alfred Marshall, A.C. Pigou, and John Maynard Keynes, associated with Cambridge University, focusing on money demand instead of money supply, argued that a certain portion of the money supply will not be used for transactions, but instead it will be held for the convenience and security of having cash on hand. This proportion of cash is commonly represented as , a portion of nominal income (). (The Cambridge economists also thought wealth would play a role, but wealth is often omitted for simplicity.) The Cambridge equation for demand for cash balances is thus:[1]

which, given the classical dichotomy and that real income must equal expenditures , is equivalent to

Assuming that the economy is at equilibrium (), that real income is exogenous, and that k is fixed in the short run, the Cambridge equation is equivalent to the equation of exchange with velocity equal to the inverse of k:

The money demand function is often conceptualized in terms of a liquidity function, ,

where is real income and is the real rate of interest. If is taken to be a function of , then in equilibrium

History

The equation of exchange was stated by John Stuart Mill[2] who expanded on the ideas of David Hume.[3] The algebraic formulation comes from Irving Fisher, 1911.

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Froyen, Richard T. Macroeconomics: Theories and Policies. 3rd Edition. Macmillan Publishing Company: New York, 1990. p. 70-71.
  2. ^ Mill, John Stuart; Principles of Political Economy (1848).
  3. ^ Hume, David; “Of Interest” in Essays Moral and Political.

References