Mental accounting: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
→‎Public policy: improve citation
No edit summary
Line 4: Line 4:
'''Mental accounting''' (or '''psychological accounting''') is a model of [[consumer behaviour]] developed by [[Richard Thaler]] that attempts to describe the process whereby people code, categorize and evaluate [[economic]] outcomes.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Zhang|first1=C. Yiwei|last2=Sussman|first2=Abigail B.|date=2018|title=Perspectives on mental accounting: An exploration of budgeting and investing|journal=Financial Planning Review|language=en|volume=1|issue=1–2|pages=e1011|doi=10.1002/cfp2.1011|issn=2573-8615|doi-access=free}}</ref> Mental accounting incorporates the economic concepts of [[prospect theory]] and [https://www.acrwebsite.org/volumes/6118/volumes/v10/na-10 transactional utility theory] to evaluate how people create distinctions between their financial resources in the form of mental accounts, which in turn impacts the [[buyer decision process]] and reaction to economic outcomes. <ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Chen |first1=Li |last2=Kök |first2=A. Gürhan |last3=Tong |first3=Jordan D. |date=2013 |title=The Effect of Payment Schemes on Inventory Decisions: The Role of Mental Accounting |url=https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638 |journal=Management Science |language=en |volume=59 |issue=2 |pages=436–451 |doi=10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638 |issn=0025-1909 |via=JSTOR}}</ref> People are presumed to make mental accounts as a self control strategy to manage and keep track of their spending and resources.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Cheema|first1=Amar|last2=Soman|first2=Dilip|date=January 2006|title=Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions|journal=Journal of Consumer Psychology|volume=16|issue=1|pages=33–44|doi=10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6}}</ref> People budget money into mental accounts for savings (e.g., saving for a home) or expense categories (e.g., gas money, clothing, utilities).<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Henderson |first1=Pamela W |last2=Peterson |first2=Robert A |date=1992-02-01 |title=Mental accounting and categorization |journal=Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes |volume=51 |issue=1 |pages=92–117 |doi=10.1016/0749-5978(92)90006-S |issn=0749-5978}}</ref> People also are assumed to make mental accounts to facilitate savings for larger purposes (e.g., a home or college tuition).<ref>{{Cite book|title=Why smart people make big money mistakes and how to correct them : lessons from the life-changing science of behavioral economics|last=Belsky, Gary.|date=2014|publisher=Simon & Schuster|isbn=9781439169742|oclc=892939349}}</ref> Mental accounting can result in people demonstrating greater [[loss aversion]] for certain mental accounts, resulting in [[Cognitive biases in decision-making|cognitive bias]] that incentivizes systematic departures from consumer [[Rationality (economics)|rationality]]. Through increased understanding of mental accounting differences in decision making based on different resources, and different reactions based on similar outcomes can be greater understood.
'''Mental accounting''' (or '''psychological accounting''') is a model of [[consumer behaviour]] developed by [[Richard Thaler]] that attempts to describe the process whereby people code, categorize and evaluate [[economic]] outcomes.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Zhang|first1=C. Yiwei|last2=Sussman|first2=Abigail B.|date=2018|title=Perspectives on mental accounting: An exploration of budgeting and investing|journal=Financial Planning Review|language=en|volume=1|issue=1–2|pages=e1011|doi=10.1002/cfp2.1011|issn=2573-8615|doi-access=free}}</ref> Mental accounting incorporates the economic concepts of [[prospect theory]] and [https://www.acrwebsite.org/volumes/6118/volumes/v10/na-10 transactional utility theory] to evaluate how people create distinctions between their financial resources in the form of mental accounts, which in turn impacts the [[buyer decision process]] and reaction to economic outcomes. <ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Chen |first1=Li |last2=Kök |first2=A. Gürhan |last3=Tong |first3=Jordan D. |date=2013 |title=The Effect of Payment Schemes on Inventory Decisions: The Role of Mental Accounting |url=https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638 |journal=Management Science |language=en |volume=59 |issue=2 |pages=436–451 |doi=10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638 |issn=0025-1909 |via=JSTOR}}</ref> People are presumed to make mental accounts as a self control strategy to manage and keep track of their spending and resources.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Cheema|first1=Amar|last2=Soman|first2=Dilip|date=January 2006|title=Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions|journal=Journal of Consumer Psychology|volume=16|issue=1|pages=33–44|doi=10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6}}</ref> People budget money into mental accounts for savings (e.g., saving for a home) or expense categories (e.g., gas money, clothing, utilities).<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Henderson |first1=Pamela W |last2=Peterson |first2=Robert A |date=1992-02-01 |title=Mental accounting and categorization |journal=Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes |volume=51 |issue=1 |pages=92–117 |doi=10.1016/0749-5978(92)90006-S |issn=0749-5978}}</ref> People also are assumed to make mental accounts to facilitate savings for larger purposes (e.g., a home or college tuition).<ref>{{Cite book|title=Why smart people make big money mistakes and how to correct them : lessons from the life-changing science of behavioral economics|last=Belsky, Gary.|date=2014|publisher=Simon & Schuster|isbn=9781439169742|oclc=892939349}}</ref> Mental accounting can result in people demonstrating greater [[loss aversion]] for certain mental accounts, resulting in [[Cognitive biases in decision-making|cognitive bias]] that incentivizes systematic departures from consumer [[Rationality (economics)|rationality]]. Through increased understanding of mental accounting differences in decision making based on different resources, and different reactions based on similar outcomes can be greater understood.


As Thaler puts it, “All organizations, from [[General Motors]] down to single person households, have explicit and/or implicit accounting systems. The accounting system often influences decisions in unexpected ways”.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Thaler|first=Richard|date=2008|title=Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice|journal=Marketing Science|volume=27|pages=15–25|doi=10.1287/mksc.1070.0330|s2cid=6137713 }}</ref> We often see consumer behavior deviate from the standard economic prediction; mental accounting is a framework that seeks to further explain consumer behavior, and describe when consumers might violate standard economic principles. Particularly, individual expenses will usually not be considered in conjunction with the present value of one’s total wealth; they will be instead considered in the context of two accounts: the current budgetary period (this could be a monthly process due to bills, or yearly due to an annual income), and the category of expense. People can even have multiple mental accounts for the same kind of resource. A person may use different monthly budgets for grocery shopping and eating out at restaurants, for example, and constrain one kind of purchase when its budget has run out while not constraining the other kind of purchase, even though both expenditures draw on the same fungible resource (income).<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions|journal = Journal of Consumer Psychology|date = 2006-01-01|pages = 33–44|volume = 16|issue = 1|doi = 10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6|first1 = Amar|last1 = Cheema|first2 = Dilip|last2 = Soman}}</ref>
As Thaler puts it, “All organizations, from [[General Motors]] down to single person households, have explicit and/or implicit accounting systems. The accounting system often influences decisions in unexpected ways”.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Thaler|first=Richard|date=2008|title=Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice|journal=Marketing Science|volume=27|pages=15–25|doi=10.1287/mksc.1070.0330|s2cid=6137713 }}</ref> Particularly, individual expenses will usually not be considered in conjunction with the present value of one’s total wealth; they will be instead considered in the context of two accounts: the current budgetary period (this could be a monthly process due to bills, or yearly due to an annual income), and the category of expense. <ref>{{Cite journal |last=Muehlbacher |first=Stephan |last2=Kirchler |first2=Erich |date=2019-12-18 |title=Individual Differences in Mental Accounting |url=https://www.frontiersin.org/article/10.3389/fpsyg.2019.02866/full |journal=Frontiers in Psychology |volume=10 |pages=2866 |doi=10.3389/fpsyg.2019.02866 |issn=1664-1078 |pmc=PMC6930806 |pmid=31920887}}</ref> People can even have multiple mental accounts for the same kind of resource. A person may use different monthly budgets for grocery shopping and eating out at restaurants, for example, and constrain one kind of purchase when its budget has run out while not constraining the other kind of purchase, even though both expenditures draw on the same fungible resource (income).<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions|journal = Journal of Consumer Psychology|date = 2006-01-01|pages = 33–44|volume = 16|issue = 1|doi = 10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6|first1 = Amar|last1 = Cheema|first2 = Dilip|last2 = Soman}}</ref>


One detailed application of mental accounting, the Behavioral Life Cycle Hypothesis posits that people mentally frame assets as belonging to either current income, current wealth or future income and this has implications for their behavior as the accounts are largely non-fungible and [[marginal propensity to consume]] out of each account is different. <ref>{{Cite journal |last=Shefrin |first=Hersh M. |last2=Thaler |first2=Richard H. |date=1988 |title=THE BEHAVIORAL LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01520.x |journal=Economic Inquiry |language=en |volume=26 |issue=4 |pages=609–643 |doi=10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01520.x}}</ref>
One detailed application of mental accounting, the Behavioral Life Cycle Hypothesis posits that people mentally frame assets as belonging to either current income, current wealth or future income and this has implications for their behavior as the accounts are largely non-fungible and [[marginal propensity to consume]] out of each account is different. <ref>{{Cite journal |last=Shefrin |first=Hersh M. |last2=Thaler |first2=Richard H. |date=1988 |title=THE BEHAVIORAL LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01520.x |journal=Economic Inquiry |language=en |volume=26 |issue=4 |pages=609–643 |doi=10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01520.x}}</ref>
Line 22: Line 22:
Integration and segregation of outcomes is a means of [[Framing (social sciences)|framing]] that can impact the overall utility derived from multiple outcomes. Mental accounting interprets the tendency of people to mentally segregate their financial resources into different categories. In the event of financial losses or gains in different mental accounts, people will be impacted differently than if the financial loss was integrated across their entire financial portfolio. In the event of multiple gain and mixed loss, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in maximised utility. In the event of multiple losses and mixed gain, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in minimized utility.
Integration and segregation of outcomes is a means of [[Framing (social sciences)|framing]] that can impact the overall utility derived from multiple outcomes. Mental accounting interprets the tendency of people to mentally segregate their financial resources into different categories. In the event of financial losses or gains in different mental accounts, people will be impacted differently than if the financial loss was integrated across their entire financial portfolio. In the event of multiple gain and mixed loss, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in maximised utility. In the event of multiple losses and mixed gain, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in minimized utility.


There are two [[Value (economics)|value]]s attached to any transaction - acquisition value and transaction value. ''Acquisition value'' is the money that one is ready to part with for physically acquiring some good.<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal |last=Grewal |first=Dhruv |last2=Monroe |first2=Kent B. |last3=Krishnan |first3=R. |date=1998 |title=The Effects of Price-Comparison Advertising on Buyers' Perceptions of Acquisition Value, Transaction Value, and Behavioral Intentions |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1252160 |journal=Journal of Marketing |volume=62 |issue=2 |pages=46–59 |doi=10.2307/1252160 |issn=0022-2429}}</ref> ''Transaction value'' is the value one attaches to having a good deal.<ref name=":1" /> If the price that one is paying is equal to the mental reference price for the good, the transaction value is zero. If the price is lower than the reference price, the transaction utility is positive. Total utility received from a transaction, then, is the sum of acquisition utility and transaction utility.
There are two [[Value (economics)|value]]s attached to any transaction - acquisition value and transaction value. ''Acquisition value'' is the money that one is ready to part with for physically acquiring some good.<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal |last=Grewal |first=Dhruv |last2=Monroe |first2=K. |last3=Krishnan |first3=R. |date=1998 |title=The Effects of Price-Comparison Advertising on Buyers Perceptions of Acquisition Value, Transaction Value, and Behavioral Intentions |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1252160 |journal=Journal of Marketing |volume=62 |issue=2 |pages=46–59 |doi=10.2307/1252160 |issn=0022-2429}}</ref> ''Transaction value'' is the value one attaches to having a good deal.<ref name=":1" /> If the price that one is paying is equal to the mental reference price for the good, the transaction value is zero. If the price is lower than the reference price, the transaction utility is positive. Total utility received from a transaction, then, is the sum of acquisition utility and transaction utility.


=== Pain of Paying ===
=== Pain of Paying ===

Revision as of 03:02, 26 April 2023

An example of mental accounting is people's willingness to pay more for goods when using credit cards than if they are paying with cash.[1] This phenomenon is referred to as payment decoupling.

Mental accounting (or psychological accounting) is a model of consumer behaviour developed by Richard Thaler that attempts to describe the process whereby people code, categorize and evaluate economic outcomes.[2] Mental accounting incorporates the economic concepts of prospect theory and transactional utility theory to evaluate how people create distinctions between their financial resources in the form of mental accounts, which in turn impacts the buyer decision process and reaction to economic outcomes. [3] People are presumed to make mental accounts as a self control strategy to manage and keep track of their spending and resources.[4] People budget money into mental accounts for savings (e.g., saving for a home) or expense categories (e.g., gas money, clothing, utilities).[5] People also are assumed to make mental accounts to facilitate savings for larger purposes (e.g., a home or college tuition).[6] Mental accounting can result in people demonstrating greater loss aversion for certain mental accounts, resulting in cognitive bias that incentivizes systematic departures from consumer rationality. Through increased understanding of mental accounting differences in decision making based on different resources, and different reactions based on similar outcomes can be greater understood.

As Thaler puts it, “All organizations, from General Motors down to single person households, have explicit and/or implicit accounting systems. The accounting system often influences decisions in unexpected ways”.[7] Particularly, individual expenses will usually not be considered in conjunction with the present value of one’s total wealth; they will be instead considered in the context of two accounts: the current budgetary period (this could be a monthly process due to bills, or yearly due to an annual income), and the category of expense. [8] People can even have multiple mental accounts for the same kind of resource. A person may use different monthly budgets for grocery shopping and eating out at restaurants, for example, and constrain one kind of purchase when its budget has run out while not constraining the other kind of purchase, even though both expenditures draw on the same fungible resource (income).[9]

One detailed application of mental accounting, the Behavioral Life Cycle Hypothesis posits that people mentally frame assets as belonging to either current income, current wealth or future income and this has implications for their behavior as the accounts are largely non-fungible and marginal propensity to consume out of each account is different. [10]

Utility, value and transaction

In mental accounting theory, the framing effect defines that the way a person subjectively frames a transaction in their mind will determine the utility they receive or expect.[11] The concept of framing is adopted in prospect theory, which is commonly used by mental accounting theorists as the value function in their analysis (Richard Thaler Included [12]). In Prospect Theory, the value function is concave for gains (implying an aversion to risk), indicating decreasing marginal utility with accumulation of gain. The value function is convex for losses (implying a risk-seeking attitude). A concave value function for gain incentivizes risk-averse behavior because marginal gain decreases relative increase in value. Conversely a convex value function for losses means that the impact of a loss is more detrimental to a person than an equivalent gain, thus incentivizing risk-seeking behavior in order to avoid loss. These proponents of the value function portray the concept of loss aversion, which asserts that people are more likely to make decisions in order to minimize loss than to maximise gain.[13]

Given the Prospect Theory framework, how do people interpret, or ‘account for’, multiple transactions/outcomes, of the format ? They can either view the outcomes jointly, and receive , in which case the outcomes are integrated, or , in which case we say that the outcomes are segregated. The choice to integrate or segregate multiple outcomes can be beneficial or detrimental to overall utility depending on correctness of application.[14] Due to the nature of our value function’s different slopes for gains and losses, our utility is maximized in different ways, depending on how we code the four kinds of transactions and (as gains or as losses):

This graph shows how with two outcomes that in aggregate make up a mixed loss, more value is achieved by treating the outcomes separately. This is the "silver lining".

1) Multiple gains: and are both considered gains. Here, we see that . Thus, we want to segregate multiple gains.

2) Multiple losses: and are both considered losses. Here, we see that . We want to integrate multiple losses.

3) Mixed gain: one of and is a gain and one is a loss, however the gain is the larger of the two. In this case, . Utility is maximized when we integrate a mixed gain.

4) Mixed loss: again, one of and is a gain and one is a loss, however the loss is now significantly larger than the gain. In this case, . Clearly, we don't want to integrate a mixed loss when the less is significantly larger than the gain. This is often referred to as a "silver lining", a reference to the folk maxim "every cloud has a silver lining". When the loss is just barely larger than the gain, integration may be preferred.

Integration and segregation of outcomes is a means of framing that can impact the overall utility derived from multiple outcomes. Mental accounting interprets the tendency of people to mentally segregate their financial resources into different categories. In the event of financial losses or gains in different mental accounts, people will be impacted differently than if the financial loss was integrated across their entire financial portfolio. In the event of multiple gain and mixed loss, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in maximised utility. In the event of multiple losses and mixed gain, mental accounting will segregate outcomes resulting in minimized utility.

There are two values attached to any transaction - acquisition value and transaction value. Acquisition value is the money that one is ready to part with for physically acquiring some good.[15] Transaction value is the value one attaches to having a good deal.[15] If the price that one is paying is equal to the mental reference price for the good, the transaction value is zero. If the price is lower than the reference price, the transaction utility is positive. Total utility received from a transaction, then, is the sum of acquisition utility and transaction utility.

Pain of Paying

A more proximal psychological mechanism through which mental accounting influences spending is through its influence on the pain of paying that is associated with spending money from a mental account.[16] Pain of paying is a negative affective response associated with a financial loss. Prototypical examples are the unpleasant feeling that one experiences when watching the fare increase on a taximeter or at the gas pump. When considering an expense, consumers appear to compare the cost of the expense to the size of an account that it would deplete (e.g., numerator vs. denominator).[17] A $30 t-shirt, for example, would be a subjectively larger expense when drawn from $50 in one's wallet than $500 in one's checking account. The larger the fraction, the more pain of paying the purchase appears to generate and the less likely consumers are to then exchange money for the good. Other evidence of the relation between pain of paying and spending include the lower debt held by consumers who report experiencing a higher pain of paying for the same goods and services than consumers who report experiencing less pain of paying.[18]

Main principles of mental accounts

Richard Thaler divided the concept mental accounting into two main principles; segregation of gains and losses, and account reference points. [19] Both principles utilize concepts related to utility and pain of paying to interpret how people evaluate economic outcomes.

Segregation of gains and losses

A main principle of mental accounting is the assertion that people frame gains and losses by segregating into different mental accounts rather than integrating into their overall account. The impact of this tendency means that outcomes can be framed based on the context of a decision. In mental accounting the framing of a decision reduces from the overall account to a smaller segregated account which can incentivize purchase decisions. An example of this was posed by Thaler where people were more inclined to drive 20 minutes to save $5 on a $15 purchase than on a $125 purchase [19]. The principle applies to mental accounting where if gains and losses are viewed relative to a smaller segregated account then the outcome is viewed differently.

Account reference points

Account reference points refer to the tendency for people to set a reference point on a current decision based on prior outcome in the same mental account. As a result the impact of prior outcomes integrate into the current decision when determining overall utility. An example was posed by Thaler where gamblers were more inclined to make risk-seeking bets on the last race of the day. [19] This phenomenon was justified by the assertion that gamblers segregate the gains and losses from each day into separate accounts and integrate gains and losses for each day in an account.[19] It can then be interpreted that end-of-day risk-seeking bets is an example of loss aversion where gamblers attempt to equalize their daily account.

Practical implications

Since the inception of the concept, mental accounting has been applied to interpret consumer behavior particularly in the contexts of online shopping, consumer reward points, public taxation policy.

Psychology

Mental accounting is subject to many logical fallacies and cognitive biases,[20] which hold many implications such as overspending.[21]

Credit cards and cash payments

Another example of mental accounting is the greater willingness to pay for goods when using credit cards than cash.[22]

If one uses a credit card to pay for tickets to a sporting event, they will tend to be willing to pay more than if they made their bid with cash. This phenomenon is also related to transaction decoupling, the separation of when a good is acquired and when it is actually paid for. Swiping a credit card prolongs the payment to a later date (when we pay our monthly bill) and it adds it to a large existing sum (our bill to that point). This delay causes the payment to stick in our memory less clearly and saliently. Furthermore, the payment is no longer perceived in isolation; rather, it is seen as a (relatively) small increase of an already large credit card bill. For example, it might be a change from $120 to $125, instead of a regular, out-of-pocket $5 cost. And as we can see from our value function, this V(-$125) – V(-$120) is smaller than V(-$5). This phenomenon is referred to as payment decoupling.

Marketing

Mental accounting is useful for marketers, in particular, as it makes useful predictions for how consumers will respond to different ways of presenting losses and gains. People respond more positively to incentives and costs when gains are segregated, losses are integrated, marketers segregate net losses (the silver lining principle), and integrate net gains. Automotive dealers, for example, benefit from these principles when they bundle optional features into a single price but segregate each feature included in the bundle (e.g., heated seats, heated steering wheel, mirror defrosters). Cellular phone companies can use principles of mental accounting when deciding how much to charge consumers for a new smartphone and to give them for their trade-in. When the cost of the phone is large and the value of the phone to be traded in is low, it is better to charge consumers a slightly higher price for the phone and return that money to them as a higher value on their trade in. Conversely, when the cost of the phone and the value of the trade-in are more comparable, because consumers are loss averse, it is better to charge them less for the new phone and offer them less for the trade-in.[23]

Public policy

Mental accounting can also be utilized in public economics and public policy. Policy-makers and public economists would do well to consider mental accounting when crafting public systems, trying to understand and identify market failures, redistribute wealth or resources in a fair way, reduce the saliency of sunk costs, limiting or eliminating the Free-rider problem, or even just when delivering bundles of multiple goods or services to taxpayers. Inherently, the way that people (and therefore taxpayer and voters) perceive decisions and outcomes will be influenced by their process of mental accounting. If policy-makers consider the implications of how people mentally book-keep their decisions, they should be able to frame and construct public policy that results in better decisions for health, wealth, and happiness.

A good example of the importance of considering mental accounting while crafting public policy is demonstrated by authors Justine Hastings and Jesse Shapiro in their analysis of the SNAP (Supplemental Nutritional Assistance Program). They "argue that these findings are not consistent with households treating SNAP funds as fungible with non-SNAP funds, and we support this claim with formal tests of fungibility that allow different households to have different consumption functions"[24] Put differently, their data supports Thaler's (and the concept of mental accounting's) claim that the principle of fungibility is often violated in practice. Furthermore, they find SNAP to be very effective, calculating a marginal propensity to consume SNAP-eligible food (MPCF) out of benefits received by SNAP of 0.5 to 0.6. This is much higher than the MPCF out of cash transfers, which is usually around 0.1. Clearly, mental accounting is leveraged by SNAP to make it a more effective policy.

Authors Emmanuel Farhi and Xavier Gabaix examine the implications of mental accounting for taxation in their paper: Optimal Taxation with Behavioral Insights. The authors main goal is to revisit the three pillars of optimal taxation, and add a behavioral twist to them which tries to incorporate mental accounting (as well as misperceptions and internalities). They reach a number of novel economic insights, showing how to incorporate nudges in the optimal taxation frameworks, and challenging the Diamond-Mirrlees productive efficiency result and the Atkinson-Stiglitz uniform commodity taxation proposition, finding they are more likely to fail with behavioral agents.[25]

In the paper Public vs. Private Mental Accounts: Experimental Evidence from Savings Groups in Colombia, Luz Magdalena Salas shows how mental accounting can be exploited to help nudge people towards saving more. In the randomized control trial that she runs, we see that labeling savings goals in different ways can lead to different levels of success in achieving savings goals.[26] Further, the power of this labeling effect differs based on the saving success that people were having to begin with.

Mental accounting plays a powerful role in our decision-making processes. It is important for public policy experts, researchers, and policy-makers continue to explore the ways that it can be utilized to benefit public welfare.

See also

References

  1. ^ Prelec, Drazen; Simester, Duncan (2001-02-01). "Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay". Marketing Letters. 12 (1): 5–12. doi:10.1023/A:1008196717017. ISSN 0923-0645. S2CID 18207187.
  2. ^ Zhang, C. Yiwei; Sussman, Abigail B. (2018). "Perspectives on mental accounting: An exploration of budgeting and investing". Financial Planning Review. 1 (1–2): e1011. doi:10.1002/cfp2.1011. ISSN 2573-8615.
  3. ^ Chen, Li; Kök, A. Gürhan; Tong, Jordan D. (2013). "The Effect of Payment Schemes on Inventory Decisions: The Role of Mental Accounting". Management Science. 59 (2): 436–451. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638. ISSN 0025-1909 – via JSTOR.
  4. ^ Cheema, Amar; Soman, Dilip (January 2006). "Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions". Journal of Consumer Psychology. 16 (1): 33–44. doi:10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6.
  5. ^ Henderson, Pamela W; Peterson, Robert A (1992-02-01). "Mental accounting and categorization". Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 51 (1): 92–117. doi:10.1016/0749-5978(92)90006-S. ISSN 0749-5978.
  6. ^ Belsky, Gary. (2014). Why smart people make big money mistakes and how to correct them : lessons from the life-changing science of behavioral economics. Simon & Schuster. ISBN 9781439169742. OCLC 892939349.
  7. ^ Thaler, Richard (2008). "Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice". Marketing Science. 27: 15–25. doi:10.1287/mksc.1070.0330. S2CID 6137713.
  8. ^ Muehlbacher, Stephan; Kirchler, Erich (2019-12-18). "Individual Differences in Mental Accounting". Frontiers in Psychology. 10: 2866. doi:10.3389/fpsyg.2019.02866. ISSN 1664-1078. PMC 6930806. PMID 31920887.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: PMC format (link) CS1 maint: unflagged free DOI (link)
  9. ^ Cheema, Amar; Soman, Dilip (2006-01-01). "Malleable Mental Accounting: The Effect of Flexibility on the Justification of Attractive Spending and Consumption Decisions". Journal of Consumer Psychology. 16 (1): 33–44. doi:10.1207/s15327663jcp1601_6.
  10. ^ Shefrin, Hersh M.; Thaler, Richard H. (1988). "THE BEHAVIORAL LIFE-CYCLE HYPOTHESIS". Economic Inquiry. 26 (4): 609–643. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01520.x.
  11. ^ Cartwright, Edward (2018). Behavioral Economics (3rd ed.). Routledge. ISBN 9781138097124.
  12. ^ Thaler, Richard H. (1985). "Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice". Marketing Science. 27 (1): 15–25. doi:10.1287/mksc.1070.0330. ISSN 0732-2399. S2CID 6137713 – via JSTOR.
  13. ^ Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (1992-10-01). "Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 5 (4): 297–323. doi:10.1007/BF00122574. ISSN 1573-0476.
  14. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (2013), "Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk", Handbook of the Fundamentals of Financial Decision Making, World Scientific Handbook in Financial Economics Series, vol. 4, World Scientific, pp. 99–127, doi:10.1142/9789814417358_0006, ISBN 978-981-4417-34-1, retrieved 2023-04-26
  15. ^ a b Grewal, Dhruv; Monroe, K.; Krishnan, R. (1998). "The Effects of Price-Comparison Advertising on Buyers Perceptions of Acquisition Value, Transaction Value, and Behavioral Intentions". Journal of Marketing. 62 (2): 46–59. doi:10.2307/1252160. ISSN 0022-2429.
  16. ^ Prelec, Drazen; Loewenstein, George (1998-02-01). "The Red and the Black: Mental Accounting of Savings and Debt". Marketing Science. 17 (1): 4–28. doi:10.1287/mksc.17.1.4. ISSN 0732-2399.
  17. ^ Morewedge, Carey K.; Holtzman, Leif; Epley, Nicholas (2007-12-01). "Unfixed Resources: Perceived Costs, Consumption, and the Accessible Account Effect". Journal of Consumer Research. 34 (4): 459–467. doi:10.1086/518540. ISSN 0093-5301. S2CID 4837702.
  18. ^ Rick, Scott I.; Cryder, Cynthia E.; Loewenstein, George (2008-04-01). "Tightwads and Spendthrifts". Journal of Consumer Research. 34 (6): 767–782. doi:10.1086/523285. ISSN 0093-5301.
  19. ^ a b c d Thaler, Richard H. (1999). <183::aid-bdm318>3.0.co;2-f "Mental accounting matters". Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. 12 (3): 183–206. doi:10.1002/(sici)1099-0771(199909)12:3<183::aid-bdm318>3.0.co;2-f. ISSN 0894-3257.
  20. ^ Belsky, Gary (2010). Why smart people make big money mistakes - and how to correct them ; lessons from the new science of behavioral economics. New York: Simon and Schuster. ISBN 9781439163368.
  21. ^ Sui, Lu; Sun, Lijuan; Geyfman, Victoria (2020-09-09). "An assessment of the effects of mental accounting on overspending behaviour: An empirical study". International Journal of Consumer Studies. 45 (2): 221–234. doi:10.1111/ijcs.12613. ISSN 1470-6423. S2CID 225306603.
  22. ^ Prelec, Drazen; Simester, Duncan (2001-02-01). "Always Leave Home Without It: A Further Investigation of the Credit-Card Effect on Willingness to Pay". Marketing Letters. 12 (1): 5–12. doi:10.1023/A:1008196717017. ISSN 0923-0645. S2CID 18207187.
  23. ^ Kim, Jungkeun; Rao, Raghunath Singh; Kim, Kyeongheui; Rao, Akshay R. (2011-02-01). "More or Less: A Model and Empirical Evidence on Preferences for Under- and Overpayment in Trade-In Transactions". Journal of Marketing Research. 48 (1): 157–171. doi:10.1509/jmkr.48.1.157. hdl:10292/2114. ISSN 0022-2437. S2CID 16350407.
  24. ^ Hastings, Shapiro (February 2018). "How Are SNAP Benefits Spent? Evidence From a Retail Panel" (PDF). NBER.
  25. ^ Farhi, Emmanuel; Gabaix, Xavier (2015). Optimal Taxation with Behavioral Agents (Working Paper). National Bureau of Economic Research. doi:10.3386/w21524. 21524.
  26. ^ Salas (March 2014). "Public vs. Private Mental Accounts: Experimental Evidence from Savings Groups in Colombia". City University of New York – Graduate Center.

Bibliography