Jump to content

Jules Dupuit

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Dupuit)

Jules Dupuit
Jules Dupuit
Born(1804-05-18)18 May 1804
Fossano, Cisalpine Republic
Died5 September 1866(1866-09-05) (aged 62)
Paris, France
NationalityFrench
Alma mater
Scientific career
FieldsEconomics, Engineering
Institutions Inspector-general of Bridges and Roads (Corps des Ingénieurs des Ponts et Chaussées (IPC))

Arsène Jules Étienne Juvenal Dupuit (18 May 1804 – 5 September 1866) was a French civil engineer and economist.[1][2][3]

He was born in Fossano, Cisalpine Republic then under the rule of Napoleon Bonaparte. At the age of ten he went to Versailles with his family where he studied — winning a Physics prize at graduation. He then studied in the École Polytechnique as a civil engineer. He gradually took on more responsibility in various regional posts. He received a Légion d'honneur in 1843 for his work on the French road system, and shortly after moved to Paris. He also studied flood management in 1848 and supervised the construction of the Paris sewer system. He died in Paris.

Engineering questions led to his interest in economics, a subject in which he was self-taught. His 1844 article was concerned with deciding the optimum toll for a bridge. It was here that he introduced his curve of diminishing marginal utility. As the quantity of a good consumed rises, the marginal utility of the good declines for the user. So the lower the toll (lower marginal utility), the more people who would use the bridge (higher consumption). Conversely as the quantity rises (people allowed on the bridge), the willingness of a person to pay for that good (the price) declines.

Thus, the concept of diminishing marginal utility should translate itself into a downward-sloping demand function. In this way he identified the demand curve as the marginal utility curve. This was the first time an economist had put forward a theory of demand derived from marginal utility. Although not the first time that the demand curve had been drawn, it was the first time that it had been proved rather than asserted. Dupuit, however, did not include a supply curve in his theory.

Dupuit went on to define "relative utility" as the area under the demand/marginal utility curve above the price and used it as a measure of the welfare effects of different prices – concluding that public welfare is maximized when the price (or bridge toll) is zero. This was later known as Marshall's "consumer surplus".

Dupuit's reputation as an economist does not rest on his advocacy of laissez-faire economics (he wrote "Commercial Freedom" in 1861) but on frequent contributions to periodicals. Wanting to evaluate the net economic benefit of public services, Dupuit analysed capacities for economic development, and attempted to construct a framework for utility theory and measuring the prosperity derived with public works. He also wrote on monopoly and price discrimination.

Dupuit also considered the groundwater flow equation, which governs the flow of groundwater. He assumed that the equation could be simplified for analytical solutions by assuming that groundwater is hydrostatic and flows horizontally. This assumption is regularly used today, and is known by hydrogeologists as the Dupuit assumption.

Works

[edit]
  • "De la mesure de l'utilité des travaux publics". Annales des ponts et chaussées: Partie technique. Mémoires et documents. 8: 332–375. 1844 – via Google Books.

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Blaug, Mark, ed. (1986). "Dupuit, Arsène Jules Étienne Juvenal". Who's Who in Economics: A Biographical Dictionary of Major Economists 1700-1986 (2nd ed.). Wheatsheaf Books Limited. p. 234-235. ISBN 978-0-7450-0230-9 – via Internet Archive.
  2. ^ Vickrey, William S. (1968). "Dupuit, Jules". In Sills, David L. (ed.). International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences. Vol. 4. The Macmillan Company & The Free Press. pp. 308-311 – via Internet Archive.
  3. ^ Rutherford, Donald (2002). "Dupuit, Arsène Jules Étienne Juvenal (1804-1866)". Routledge Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). London and New York: Routledge. p. 154 – via Internet Archive.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
[edit]