Cooperative: Difference between revisions
Appearance
Content deleted Content added
Pgravinese (talk | contribs) |
←Replaced content with '{{About|the business organization||Coop (disambiguation)}} A '''cooperative''' (also '''co-operative'''; often referred to as a '''co-op''') is a business organ...' |
||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{About|the business organization||Coop (disambiguation)}} |
{{About|the business organization||Coop (disambiguation)}} |
||
A '''cooperative''' (also '''co-operative'''; often referred to as a '''co-op''') is a business organization owned and operated by a group of individuals for their mutual benefit.<ref>{{Cite book |
A '''cooperative''' (also '''co-operative'''; often referred to as a '''co-op''') is a business organization owned and operated by a group of individuals for their mutual benefit.<ref>{{Cite book |
||
|[[th:สหกรณ์]] |
|||
|last = O'Sullivan |
|||
|first = Arthur |
|||
|authorlink = |
|||
|coauthors = Steven M. Sheffrin |
|||
|title = Economics: Principles in action |
|||
|publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall |
|||
|year = 2003 |
|||
|location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458 |
|||
|page = 202 |
|||
|url = |
|||
|doi = |
|||
|id = |
|||
|isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref> Cooperatives are defined by the [[International Co-operative Alliance|International Co-operative Alliance's]] [[Statement on the Co-operative Identity]] as [[Autonomy|autonomous association]]s of persons united voluntarily to meet their common economic, social, and cultural needs and aspirations through jointly owned and democratically controlled [[business|enterprise]]s.<ref name="ica-principles">[http://www.ica.coop/coop/principles.html Statement on the Co-operative Identity.] ''[[International Co-operative Alliance]].''</ref> A cooperative may also be defined as a business owned and controlled equally by the people who use its services or by the people who work there. Cooperative enterprises are the focus of study in the field of [[Co-operative economics|cooperative economics]]. |
|||
[[Image:CloyneCt1.jpg|thumb|right|The [[Cloyne Court Hotel]], a [[student housing cooperative]] in [[Berkeley, California]], United States.]] |
|||
[[Image:ScotmidCoop200411 CopyrightKaihsuTai.jpg|thumb|right|[[Consumers' cooperative]] shops in the UK formed the world's first mass cooperative movement]] |
|||
==Origins== |
|||
{{Main|History of the cooperative movement}} |
|||
Cooperation dates back as far as human beings have been organizing for mutual benefit. Tribes were organised as cooperative structures, allocating jobs and resources among each other, only trading with the external communities. Post-industrial Europe is home to the first co-operatives from an industrial context. |
|||
[[File:Portrait of Robert Owen (1771 - 1858) by John Cranch, 1845.jpg|thumb|right|[[Robert Owen]] (1771 - 1858) was a social reformer and a pioneer of the cooperative movement.]] |
|||
In 1761, the [[Fenwick Weavers' Society]] was formed in [[Fenwick, East Ayrshire|Fenwick]], [[East Ayrshire]], [[Scotland]] to sell [[discounts and allowances|discount]]ed [[oatmeal]] to local workers.<ref>Carrell, Severin. [http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2007/aug/07/retail.uknews Strike Rochdale from the record books. The Co-op began in Scotland.], ''[[The Guardian]]'', 7 August 2007.</ref> Its services expanded to include assistance with savings and loans, emigration and education. In 1810, [[Welsh people|Welsh]] [[social reform]]er [[Robert Owen]], from Newtown in mid-[[Wales]], and his partners purchased [[New Lanark]] mill from Owen's father-in-law [[David Dale]] and proceeded to introduce better labor standards including discounted retail shops where profits were passed on to his employees. Owen left New Lanark to pursue other forms of co-operative organization and develop co-op ideas through writing and lecture. Co-operative communities were set up in [[Glasgow]], [[Indiana]] and [[Hampshire]], although ultimately unsuccessful. In 1828, [[William King (doctor)|William King]] set up a newspaper, ''The Cooperator'', to promote Owen's thinking, having already set up a co-operative store in [[Brighton]]. |
|||
The [[Rochdale Pioneers|Rochdale Society of Equitable Pioneers]], founded in 1844, is usually considered the first successful co-operative enterprise, used as a model for modern co-ops, following the '[[Rochdale Principles]]'. A group of 28 weavers and other artisans in [[Rochdale]], [[England]] set up the society to open their own store selling food items they could not otherwise afford. Within ten years there were over 1,000 co-operative societies in the United Kingdom. |
|||
Other events such as the founding of a [[friendly society]] by the [[Tolpuddle Martyrs]] in 1832 were key occasions in the creation of organized labor and consumer movements. |
|||
==Social economy== |
|||
In the final year of the 20th century, cooperatives banded together to establish a number of [[social enterprise]] agencies which have moved to adopt the multi-stakeholder cooperative model.<ref name = "RidleyDuff" /><ref>Brown, J. (2006), “Designing Equity Finance for Social Enterprises”, ''Social Enterprise Journal'', 2(1): 73 81.</ref> In the last 15 years (1994–2009) the [[EU]] and its member nations, have gradually revised national accounting systems to "make visible" the increasing contribution of [[social economy]] organizations.<ref>Monzon, J. L. & Chaves, R. (2008) “The European Social Economy: Concept and Dimensions of the Third Sector”, ''Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics'', 79(3/4): 549-577.</ref> |
|||
==Organizational and ideological roots== |
|||
The roots of the cooperative movement can be traced to multiple influences and extend worldwide. In the [[Anglosphere]], post-[[feudal]] forms of cooperation between workers and owners, that are expressed today as "profit-sharing" and "surplus sharing" arrangements, existed as far back as 1795.<ref>Gates, J. (1998) ''The Ownership Solution'', London: Penguin.</ref> The key ideological influence on the Anglosphere branch of the cooperative movement, however, was a ''rejection'' of the [[charity (practice)|charity]] principles that underpinned [[welfare]] reforms when the [[British government]] radically revised its [[Poor Laws]] in 1834. As both state and church institutions began to routinely distinguish between the 'deserving' and 'undeserving' poor, a movement of [[friendly society|friendly societies]] grew throughout the [[British Empire]] based on the principle of mutuality, committed to self-help in the welfare of working people. |
|||
Friendly Societies established forums through which [[one member, one vote]] was practiced in organisation decision-making. The principles challenged the idea that a person should be an owner of [[property]] before being granted a political voice.<ref name="RidleyDuff">[http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/journal/117967289/abstract Ridley-Duff, R. J. (2007) “Communitarian Perspectives on Social Enterprise”, ''Corporate Governance: An International Review'', 15(2):382-392].</ref> Throughout the second half of the nineteenth century (and then repeatedly every 20 years or so) there has been a surge in the number of cooperative organisations, both in commercial practice and civil society, operating to advance [[democracy]] and [[universal suffrage]] as a political principle.<ref>Rothschild, J., Allen-Whitt, J. (1986) ''The Cooperative Workplace'', Cambridge University Press</ref> Friendly Societies and consumer cooperatives became the dominant form of organization amongst working people in Anglosphere [[industrial societies]] prior to the rise of [[trade unions]] and industrial factories. Weinbren reports that by the end of the 19th century, over 80% of British working age men and 90% of Australian working age men were members of one or more Friendly Society.<ref name="Weinbren">[http://www.historycooperative.org/journals/lab/88/weinbren.html Weinbren, D. & James, B. (2005) “Getting a Grip: the Roles of Friendly Societies in Australia and Britain Reappraised”, Labour History, Vol. 88].</ref> |
|||
From the mid-nineteenth century, [[mutual organisation]]s embraced these ideas in economic enterprises, firstly amongst tradespeople, and later in cooperative stores, educational institutes, financial institutions and industrial enterprises. The common thread (enacted in different ways, and subject to the constraints of various systems of national law) is the principle that an enterprise or association should be owned and controlled by the people it serves, and share any surpluses on the basis of each members' cooperative contribution (as a producer, labourer or consumer) rather than their capacity to invest financial capital.<ref>[http://www.emeraldinsight.com/Insight/viewContentItem.do;jsessionid=9F0FA205C77BB6EEBEA9AB506E11BEE8?contentType=Article&contentId=1740497 Ridley-Duff, R. J. (2008) “Social Enterprise as a Socially Rational Business” , International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behaviour and Research, 14(5): 291-312].</ref> |
|||
The cooperative movement has been fueled globally by ideas of [[economic democracy]]. Economic democracy is a socioeconomic philosophy that suggests an expansion of decision-making power from a small minority of corporate shareholders to a larger majority of public stakeholders. There are many different approaches to thinking about and building economic democracy. Both [[Marxism]] and [[anarchism]], for example, have been influenced by [[utopian socialism]], which was based on voluntary cooperation, ''without'' recognition of [[class conflict]]. Anarchists are committed to [[libertarian socialism]] and they have focused on local organization, including locally managed cooperatives, linked through confederations of unions, cooperatives and communities. Marxists, who as socialists have likewise held and worked for the goal of democratizing productive and reproductive relationships, often placed a greater strategic emphasis on confronting the larger scales of human organization. As they viewed the capitalist class to be prohibitively politically, militarily and culturally mobilized in order to maintain an exploitable [[working class]], they fought in the early 20th century to appropriate from the capitalist class the society's collective political capacity in the form of [[Sovereign state|the state]], either through [[democratic socialism]], or through what came to be known as [[Leninism]]. Though they regard the state as an unnecessarily oppressive institution, Marxists considered appropriating national and international-scale capitalist institutions and resources (such as the state) to be an important first pillar in creating conditions favorable to solidaristic economies.<ref>Rothschild, J., Allen-Whitt, J. (1986) ''The cooperative workplace'', Cambridge University Press, Chapter 1.</ref><ref>Cliff, T., Cluckstein, D. (1988) ''The Labour Party: A Marxist History'', London: Bookmarks.</ref> With the declining influence of the [[USSR]] after the 1960s, socialist strategies pluralized, though economic democratizers have not as yet established a fundamental challenge to the [[hegemony]] of global [[neoliberal]] capitalism. |
|||
==Meaning== |
|||
===Cooperatives as legal entities=== |
|||
A cooperative is a [[Legal person|legal entity]] owned and democratically controlled by its members. Members often have a close association with the enterprise as producers or consumers of its products or services, or as its employees. |
|||
In some countries, e.g. [[Finland]] and [[Sweden]], there are specific forms of incorporation for co-operatives. Cooperatives may take the form of companies limited by shares or by guarantee, partnerships or unincorporated associations. In the [[USA]], cooperatives are often organized as non-capital stock corporations under state-specific cooperative laws. However, they may also be unincorporated associations or business corporations such as limited liability companies or partnerships; such forms are useful when the members want to allow: |
|||
#some members to have a greater share of the control, or |
|||
#some investors to have a return on their [[Capital (economics)|capital]] that exceeds fixed [[interest]], |
|||
neither of which may be allowed under local laws for cooperatives. Cooperatives often share their earnings with the membership as [[dividend]]s, which are divided among the members according to their participation in the enterprise, such as patronage, instead of according to the value of their capital shareholdings (as is done by a [[joint stock company]]). |
|||
===Aspects of economic rationale=== |
|||
If cooperatives/mutuals succeed, that success may reflect not the characteristics of the cooperative/mutual form itself but the existence of a long term regulated competitive environment that created the space and margins which allowed them to adopt welfare objectives different from those of profit maximising competitors. Llewellyn and Holmes (1991) argue that, in the absence of a clear efficiency advantage, mutual building societies, for example, would need to behave in a manner substantially similar to banks and mutual life insurers similarly to Plc life insurers: |
|||
"Only if mutuals have a substantial efficiency advantage compared with their Plc competitors are they able to set objectives significantly different from their Plc competitors. In the absence of this, competitive pressures force a convergence of behaviour and remove the major behavioural distinctions between mutuality and Plc's". |
|||
From this point of view, competition and narrow margins are inimical to the mutual form because they erode behavioural difference. |
|||
These issues are complicated in the case of UK building societies and mutual life insurers because they require judgement about whether they really have behaved differently in these two areas. If banks may be different from building societies, that may not be so in the case of, for example, the UK Plc 'Prudential' life insurer and its mutual competitors. But, what is clear is that building societies (like mutual life insurers) have operated in regulated areas where returns on capital are high, so that mutuals can choose different objectives. This discretion, of course, greatly complicates outcomes because mutuals can set objectives in terms of prices received or paid or in terms of market access to those who would be denied access or disadvantaged by other providers. There is also the complication that if (as in the case of building societies in the late-1980's), mutuals dominate the field, the behaviour of non-mutual competitors has to be conjectured. |
|||
Consumer attitudes and behaviour are also relevant when competition is weak. Consumers may prefer cooperatives/mutuals like building societies if they fear that surplus distributing banks might try to 'rip them off.' The point is made in the building society mutual context by Armitage (1991) in the following terms: |
|||
"In theory, in a free market with well-informed participants, competition ensures competing services are priced according to their value to the consumer; if not they do not sell. Therefore, consumers are never 'ripped off'. However to the extent that a market is less than competitive in this sense, sellers have opportunities for exploiting customers., which their duty to shareholders should oblige them to take if they are companies, and their duty to members should oblige them not to take if they are mutuals. The mortgage and deposit markets are competitive, but not perfectly so. In particular, customers have incomplete information and face search costs. So there is scope for institutional policies to make a difference to customers' welfare without always paying or gaining in terms of loss or gain of custom". |
|||
The fact that most small depositors are ill-informed (as building society depositors certainly were) may also explain the importance of mutuals in the savings markets. The Uninformed Depositor Model of Rasmusen(1988)does appear to offer explanation for why small savers prefer mutuals. In banking markets, there is usually information asymmetry whereby managers are relatively informed as to risk, such as asset risk and maturity transformation/ interest yield mismatch risk, and depositors are left relatively ignorant. In this case, the cost of virtually any monitoring by small savers is practically unsustainable. The 'free rider' effect in building societies is a manifestation of this kind of unsustainable monitoring cost where the cost of meaningful involvement in building society affairs (even attendance at the annual meeting) really quite outweighs benefits to be obtained through involvement, as Ingham and Thompson 4 point out. In earlier times, some building societies resorted to fining members for not attending annual meetings, in order to get the members to turn out. But once the roll was checked many promptly adjourned to the nearest pub ('bar'). Under these risk-monitoring circumstances, depositors will, according to Rasmusen,3 prefer a mutual where they perceive that what they understand to be moderate or no risk attaches, due to regulation, as compared to more risky less regulated banks. Also, they may understand that managers in mutuals are less motivated to take risk, as suggested by Rasmusen (1988) below and by Masulis (1987. |
|||
It could be claimed that part of the success of mutuals is due to simplified agency relationships resulting from the absence of external shareholders or to the ability to distribute surplus through product price (not 'Plc' dividend). These arguments are not conclusive, as the presence of external claimants may result in considerable pressure for cost economies, especially if there is a market for corporate control. It is doubtful that the operating cost leadership of UK building societies, which is so much a factor in the dominance of the mutual form in the savings banking and home mortgage financing market, has much to do with lower agency costs or efficiency. Before deregulation, the objective was not efficiency but growth through retained earnings which was in the management interest; and the finance directors attributed their funding cost advantage to the accident of mixed funding. Much of this detail may not matter to an uninformed depositor. As Rasmusen (1988) observes: "In the Uninformed Depositor Model the depositor does not have to distinguish motives: the advantage of the mutual is that the interests of depositors and managers roughly coincide, and whether managers are conservative to protect their perks or their depositors is a minor point". |
|||
Masulis (1987) also refers to the motivations of managers in relation to risk in the following terms with reference to American style mutual savings and loan banks where his references to 'owners' and boards of directors, in the MS&L [mutual savings and loan] context, are references to management: "Since MS&L owners (boards of directors) are only able to extract a portion of a S&L's current and accumulated earnings [through salary and perks], they have less incentive to take risks than the owners of stock companies [e.g. Plc banks] who can capture the entire stream of accumulated and expected future profits by selling their stock. |
|||
===Identity=== |
|||
<div id="Cooperative identity" /><!-- anchor for incoming links--> |
|||
Cooperatives are based on the cooperative values of "self-help, self-responsibility, democracy and equality, equity and solidarity" and the seven [[Rochdale Principles|cooperative principles]]. |
|||
#Voluntary and Open Membership |
|||
#Democratic Member Control |
|||
#Member Economic Participation |
|||
#Autonomy and Independence |
|||
#Education, Training and Information |
|||
#Cooperation among Cooperatives |
|||
#Concern for Community<ref>[http://www.ica.coop/coop/principles.html Statement on the Co-operative Identity<!-- Bot generated title -->]</ref> |
|||
In the tradition of their founders, cooperative members believe in the ethical values of honesty, openness, social responsibility and caring for others. Such legal entities have a range of unique social characteristics. Membership is open, meaning that anyone who satisfies certain non-discriminatory conditions may join. Economic benefits are distributed proportionally according to each member's level of participation in the cooperative, for instance by a dividend on sales or purchases, rather than divided according to [[capital (economics)|capital]] invested. Cooperatives may be generally classified as either '''consumer cooperatives''' or '''producer cooperatives'''. Cooperatives are closely related to [[collectives]], which differ only in that profit-making or economic stability is placed secondary to adherence to social-justice principles.{{Citation needed|date=March 2010}} Co-ops can sometimes be identified on the Internet through the use of the [[.coop]] [[gTLD]]. Organizations using .coop domain names must adhere to the basic co-op values. |
|||
==Types of cooperative governance== |
|||
===Retailers' cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Retailers' cooperative}} |
|||
A [[retailers' cooperative]] (known as a secondary or marketing co-operative in some countries) is an organization which employs [[economies of scale]] on behalf of its members to get discounts from manufacturers and to pool marketing. It is common for locally owned [[supermarket|grocery stores]], [[hardware store]]s and [[pharmacy|pharmacies]]. In this case the members of the cooperative are businesses rather than individuals. |
|||
The [[Best Western]] international hotel chain is actually a retailers' cooperative, whose members are hotel operators, although it now prefers to call itself a "nonprofit membership association." It gave up on the "cooperative" label after some courts insisted on enforcing regulatory requirements for [[franchisor]]s despite its member-controlled status. |
|||
===Worker cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Worker cooperative}} |
|||
A [[worker cooperative]] or producer cooperative is a cooperative, that is owned and democratically controlled by its "worker-owners". There are no outside owners in a "pure" workers' cooperative, only the workers own shares of the business, though hybrid forms in which consumers, community members or capitalist investors also own some shares are not uncommon. In practice, control by worker-owners may be exercised through individual, collective or majority ownership by the workforce, or the retention of individual, collective or majority voting rights (exercised on a one-member one-vote basis).<ref>Ridley-Duff, R. J. (2009) [http://digitalcommons.shu.ac.uk/ciod_papers/57/ "Cooperative Social Enterprises: Company Rules, Access to Finance and Management Practice”], ''Social Enterprise Journal'', 5(1): 50-68</ref> A worker cooperative, therefore, has the characteristic that the majority of its workforce owns shares, and the majority of shares are owned by the workforce.<ref name="ICA">[http://www.cooperatives-uk.coop/live/images/cme_resources/Public/governance/Worker%20co-op%20governance/ICA.pdf ICA (2005) World Declaration on Worker Cooperatives], Approved by the ICA General Assembly in Cartagena, Columbia, 23rd September 2005.</ref> Membership is not always compulsory for employees, but generally only employees can become members either directly (as shareholders) or indirectly through membership of a trust that owns the company. |
|||
The impact of political ideology on practice constrains the development of co-operatives in different countries. In India, there is a form of workers' cooperative which insists on compulsory membership for all employees and compulsory employment for all members. That is the form of the [[Indian Coffee House]]s. This system was advocated by the Indian communist leader [[A. K. Gopalan]]. In places like the UK, common ownership (indivisible collective ownership) was popular in the 1970s. Cooperative Societies only became legal in Britain after the passing of Slaney's Act in 1852. In 1865 there were 651 registered societies with a total membership of well over 200,000.<ref>Slaney's Act and the Christian Sociliasts: A Study of How the Industrial and Provident societies' Act 1852 was passed.</ref> There are now more than 400 worker co-operatives in the UK,<ref>[http://www.cooperatives-uk.coop/performancereview The Co‑operative Review.]{{Dead link|date=July 2010}} ''[[Co-operatives UK]].''</ref> Suma Wholefoods being the largest example with a turnover of £24 million. |
|||
Spanish law permits owner-members to register as self-employed enabling worker-owners to establish regulatory regimes that support co-operative working, but which differs considerably from co-operatives that are subject to Anglo-American systems of law that require the co-operative (employer) to view (and treat) its worker-members as salaried workers (employees).<ref>Oakeshott, R. (1990) ''The Case for Worker Co-ops (2nd Edition)'', Basingstoke: Macmillan.</ref> The implications of this are far-reaching, as this requires co-operatives to establish authority driven statutory disciplinary and grievance procedures (rather than democratic mediation schemes), impacting on the ability of leaders to enact democratic forms of management and counter the authority structures embedded in the dominant system of private enterprise centred around the entrepreneur.<ref>[http://www.roryridleyduff.com/18%20-%20Mediation%20-%20An%20Introduction.pdf Ridley-Duff, R. J. (2008) ''Mediation: Developing a Theoretical Framework for Understanding Alternative Dispute Resolution'', Centre for Individual and Organisational Development, Sheffield Hallam University], published at www.roryridleyduff.com/writingacademic.htm.</ref> |
|||
====Volunteer cooperative==== |
|||
A volunteer cooperative is a cooperative that is run by and for a network of volunteers, for the benefit of a defined membership or the general public, to achieve some goal. Depending on the structure, it may be a [[collective]] or [[mutual organization]], which is operated according to the principles of cooperative governance. The most basic form of volunteer-run cooperative is a [[voluntary association]]. A [[Fraternity|lodge]] or [[social club]] may be organized on this basis. A volunteer-run co-op is distinguished from a [[worker cooperative]] in that the latter is by definition [[Employee-owned corporation|employee-owned]], whereas the volunteer cooperative is typically a [[non-stock corporation]], volunteer-run [[consumer cooperative|consumer co-op]] or [[service organization]], in which workers and beneficiaries jointly participate in management decisions and receive discounts on the basis of [[sweat equity]]. |
|||
===Social cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Social cooperative}} |
|||
A particularly successful form of multi-stakeholder cooperative is the Italian "social cooperative", of which some 7,000 exist. "Type A" social cooperatives bring together providers and beneficiaries of a social service as members. "Type B" social cooperatives bring together permanent workers and previously unemployed people who wish to integrate into the labour market. |
|||
Social cooperatives are legally defined as follows: |
|||
*no more than 80% of profits may be distributed, interest is limited to the bond rate and dissolution is altruistic (assets may not be distributed) |
|||
*the cooperative has legal personality and limited liability |
|||
*the objective is the general benefit of the community and the social integration of citizens |
|||
*those of type B integrate disadvantaged people into the labour market. The categories of disadvantage they target may include physical and mental disability, drug and alcohol addiction, developmental disorders and problems with the law. They do not include other factors of disadvantage such as race, sexual orientation or abuse. |
|||
*type A cooperatives provide health, social or educational services |
|||
*various categories of stakeholder may become members, including paid employees, beneficiaries, volunteers (up to 50% of members), financial investors and public institutions. In type B co-operatives at least 30% of the members must be from the disadvantaged target groups |
|||
*voting is one person one vote |
|||
A good estimate of the current size of the social cooperative sector in Italy is given by updating the official [[Istituto Nazionale di Statistica]] (Istat) figures from the end of 2001 by an annual growth rate of 10% (assumed by the ''Direzione Generale per gli Ente Cooperativi''). This gives totals of 7,100 social cooperatives, with 267,000 members, 223,000 paid employees, 31,000 volunteers and 24,000 disadvantaged people undergoing integration. Combined turnover is around 5 billion euro. The cooperatives break into three types: 59% type A (social and health services), 33% type B (work integration) and 8% mixed. The average size is 30 workers. |
|||
[[Image:OSGCo-opAGM20050423 CopyrightKaihsuTai.jpg|thumb|The volunteer board of a retail [[consumers' cooperative]], such as the former [[Oxford, Swindon & Gloucester Co-operative Society|Oxford, Swindon & Gloucester Co-op]], is held to account at an Annual General Meeting of members]] |
|||
===Consumers' cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Consumers' cooperative}} |
|||
A consumers' cooperative is a business owned by its customers. Employees can also generally become members. Members vote on major decisions, and elect the board of directors from amongst their own number. |
|||
A well known example in the United States is the [[R.E.I.|REI]] (Recreational Equipment Incorporated) co-op, and in Canada: [[Mountain Equipment Co-op]]. |
|||
The world's largest consumers' cooperative is [[the Co-operative Group]] in the [[United Kingdom]], which offers a variety of retail and financial services. The UK also has a number of autonomous consumers' cooperative societies, such as the [[East of England Co-operative Society]] and [[Midcounties Co-operative]]. In fact the Co-operative Group is something of a hybrid, having both corporate members (mostly other consumers' cooperatives, as a result of its origins as a [[Co-operative wholesale society|wholesale society]]), and individual retail consumer members. |
|||
[[Legacoop]]<ref>[http://www.aboutus.org/LegaCoop.it Legacoop]</ref> in Italy has 414,383 employees, 7,736,210 members and turns over €50Bn per year growing at a steady rate of 4.41%.<ref>[http://www.thedti.gov.za/co-operative/presentations/4july/LEGACOOP.pdf Dti Reference]</ref> |
|||
Japan has a very large and well developed consumer cooperative movement with over 14 million members; retail co-ops alone had a combined turnover of 2.519 trillion Yen (21.184 billion US dollars [market exchange rates as of 15 November 2005]) in 2003/4. (Japanese Consumers' Co-operative Union., 2003). |
|||
[[Migros]] is the largest supermarket chain in Switzerland and keeps the cooperative society as its form of organization. Nowadays, a large part of the Swiss population are members of the Migros cooperative – around 2 million of Switzerland's total population of 7,2 million[1] [2], thus making Migros a supermarket chain that is owned by its customers. |
|||
[[Coop (Switzerland)|Coop]] is another Swiss cooperative which operates the second largest supermarket chain in Switzerland after Migros. In 2001, Coop merged with 11 cooperative federations which had been its main suppliers for over 100 years. |
|||
As of 2005, Coop operates 1437 shops and employs almost 45,000 people. According to Bio Suisse, the Swiss organic producers' association, Coop accounts for half of all the organic food sold in Switzerland. |
|||
[[EURO COOP]] is the European Community of Consumer Cooperatives.<ref>[http://www.eurocoop.coop/ EURO COOP]</ref> |
|||
===Business and employment co-operative=== |
|||
{{Main|Business and employment co-operative}} |
|||
'''Business and employment co-operatives''' (BECs) are a subset of worker co-operatives that represent a new approach to providing support to the creation of new businesses. |
|||
Like other business creation support schemes, BECs enable budding entrepreneurs to experiment with their business idea while benefiting from a secure income. The innovation BECs introduce is that once the business is established the entrepreneur is not forced to leave and set up independently, but can stay and become a full member of the co-operative. The micro-enterprises then combine to form one multi-activity enterprise whose members provide a mutually supportive environment for each other. |
|||
BECs thus provide budding business people with an easy transition from inactivity to self-employment, but in a collective framework. They open up new horizons for people who have ambition but who lack the skills or confidence needed to set off entirely on their own – or who simply want to carry on an independent economic activity but within a supportive group context. |
|||
==Types of cooperatives== |
|||
===Housing cooperative=== |
|||
[[Image:Co-op City Hutch River.jpg|thumb|[[Co-op City, Bronx|Co-op City]] in New York is the largest cooperative housing development in the world with 55,000 people.<ref>Whitsett, Ross. [http://cooperator.com/articles/1354/1/Urban-Mass/Page1.html Urban Mass: A Look at Co-op City.] ''[[The Cooperator]]''. December 2006.</ref>]] |
|||
{{Main|Housing cooperative}} |
|||
A [[housing cooperative]] is a legal mechanism for ownership of housing where residents either own [[shares]] (share capital co-op) reflecting their equity in the cooperative's real estate, or have membership and occupancy rights in a [[not-for-profit]] cooperative (non-share capital co-op), and they underwrite their housing through paying subscriptions or rent. |
|||
Housing cooperatives come in three basic equity structures: |
|||
*In '''Market-rate housing cooperatives''', members may sell their shares in the cooperative whenever they like for whatever price the market will bear, much like any other residential property. Market-rate co-ops are very common in [[New York City]]. |
|||
*'''Limited equity housing cooperatives''', which are often used by [[affordable housing]] developers, allow members to own some equity in their home, but limit the sale price of their membership share to that which they paid. |
|||
*'''Group equity''' or '''Zero equity housing cooperatives''' do not allow members to own equity in their residences and often have rental agreements well below market rates. |
|||
===Building cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Building cooperative}} |
|||
Members of a building cooperative (in Britain known as a self-build housing co-operative) pool resources to build housing, normally using a high proportion of their own labour. When the building is finished, each member is the sole owner of a homestead, and the cooperative may be dissolved. |
|||
This collective effort was at the origin of many of Britain's [[building societies]], which however developed into "permanent" [[Mutual organization|mutual]] [[savings and loan]] organisations, a term which persisted in some of their names (such as the former ''Leeds Permanent''). Nowadays such self-building may be financed using a step-by-step [[mortgage loan|mortgage]] which is released in stages as the building is completed. |
|||
The term may also refer to worker co-operatives in the building trade. |
|||
===Utility cooperative=== |
|||
{{Main|Utility cooperative}} |
|||
A utility cooperative is a type of [[consumers' cooperative]] that is tasked with the delivery of a [[public utility]] such as [[electricity]], [[water]] or [[telecommunications]] services to its members. [[Profit (accounting)|Profits]] are either reinvested into [[infrastructure]] or distributed to members in the form of "patronage" or "capital credits", which are essentially [[dividend]]s paid on a member's [[investment]] into the cooperative. In the United States, many cooperatives were formed to provide rural electrical and telephone service as part of the [[New Deal]]. ''See [[Rural Utilities Service]]''. |
|||
In the case of electricity, cooperatives are generally either generation and transmission (G&T) co-ops that create and send power via the transmission grid or local distribution co-ops that gather electricity from a variety of sources and send it along to homes and businesses.<ref>[http://www.ncba.coop/abcoop_util.cfm About Cooperatives: Utility Cooperatives.]{{Dead link|date=July 2010}} ''[[National Cooperative Business Association]].''</ref> |
|||
===Agricultural cooperative=== |
|||
[[Image:Graincoop.JPG|thumb|250px|right|[[Grain elevator]]s are used by agricultural cooperatives in the storage and shipping of grains.]] |
|||
{{Main|Agricultural cooperative}} |
|||
Agricultural cooperatives or farmers' cooperatives are cooperatives where [[farmer]]s pool their resources for mutual economic benefit. Agricultural cooperatives are broadly divided into ''agricultural service cooperatives'', which provide various services to their individual farming members, and ''agricultural production cooperatives'', where production resources such as land or machinery are pooled and members farm jointly.<ref name=Cobia>Cobia, David, editor, ''Cooperatives in Agriculture'', Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ (1989), p. 50.</ref> Agricultural production cooperatives are relatively rare in the world, and known examples are limited to [[collective farm]]s in [[CIS|former socialist countries]] and the [[kibbutzim]] in Israel. |
|||
Agricultural supply cooperatives aggregate purchases, storage, and distribution of farm inputs for their members. By taking advantage of volume discounts and utilizing other [[economy of scale|economies of scale]], supply cooperatives bring down members' costs. Supply cooperatives may provide seeds, fertilizers, chemicals, fuel, and farm machinery. Some supply cooperatives also operate machinery pools that provide mechanical field services (e.g., plowing, harvesting) to their members. |
|||
Agricultural marketing cooperatives provide the services involved in moving a product from the point of production to the point of consumption. [[Agricultural marketing]] includes a series of inter-connected activities involving planning production, growing and [[harvest]]ing, grading, packing, transport, storage, [[food processing]], distribution and sale. Agricultural marketing cooperatives are often formed to promote specific commodities. |
|||
===Credit unions and cooperative banking=== |
|||
{{Main|Cooperative banking|Credit union}} |
|||
[[Image:Co-operativeBankHeadOffice20051019 CopyrightKaihsuTai.jpg|thumb|right|[[The Co-operative Bank]]'s head office in [[Manchester]]. The statue in front is of [[Robert Owen]], a pioneer in the cooperative movement.]] |
|||
[[Credit union]]s are cooperative [[financial institution]]s that are owned and controlled by their members. Credit unions provide the same [[financial services]] as banks but are considered [[not-for-profit]] organizations and adhere to [[Rochdale Principles|cooperative principles]]. |
|||
Credit unions originated in mid-19th century Germany through the efforts of pioneers [[Franz Hermann Schulze-Delitzsch]] and [[Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen]]. The concept of financial cooperatives crossed the Atlantic at the turn of the 20th century, when the ''caisse populaire'' movement was started by [[Alphonse Desjardins (co-operator)|Alphonse Desjardins]] in [[Quebec]], [[Canada]]. In 1900, from his home in [[Lévis, Quebec|Lévis]], he opened North America's first credit union, marking the beginning of the [[Mouvement Desjardins]].<ref>[http://www.accessmylibrary.com/article-1G1-54036863/desjardins-model-rest-canada.html Desjardins: a model for the rest of Canada?(Quebec's Desjardins caisses populaires).] ''Canadian Banker.'' 1 January 1999.</ref> Eight years later, Desjardins provided guidance for the first credit union in the United States.<ref>[http://www.acumuseum.org/history.html Birthplace of America's Credit Union Movement.] ''[[America's Credit Union Museum]].''</ref> |
|||
While they have not taken root so deeply as in [[Ireland]] or the [[United States]], credit unions are also established in the UK. The largest are work-based, but many are now offering services in the wider community. The Association of British Credit Unions Ltd ([[ABCUL]]) represents the majority of British Credit Unions. British [[Building society|Building Societies]] developed into general-purpose savings & banking institutions with "one member, one vote" ownership and can be seen as a form of financial cooperative (although nine '[[Demutualization|de-mutualised]]' into conventionally owned banks in the 1980s & 1990s). The UK Co-operative Group includes both an [[insurance]] provider [[Co-operative Insurance Society|CIS]] and the [[Co-operative Bank]], both noted for promoting [[Ethical investing|ethical investment]]. |
|||
Other important European banking cooperatives include the [[Crédit Agricole]] in France, [[Migros]] and Coop Bank in Switzerland and the [[Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen|Raiffeisen]] system in many Central and Eastern European countries. The Netherlands, Spain, Italy and various European countries also have strong cooperative banks. They play an important part in mortgage credit and professional (i.e. farming) credit. |
|||
Cooperative banking networks, which were nationalized in Eastern Europe, work now as real cooperative institutions. A remarkable development has taken place in Poland, where the [http://www.skok.pl/ SKOK] (''Spółdzielcze Kasy Oszczędnościowo-Kredytowe'') network has grown to serve over 1 million members via 13,000 branches, and is larger than the country’s largest conventional bank. |
|||
In [[Nordic Countries|Scandinavia]], there is a clear distinction between [[mutual savings bank]]s (Sparbank) and true [[credit unions]] (Andelsbank). |
|||
===Federal or secondary cooperatives=== |
|||
{{Main|Co-operative Federation}} |
|||
In some cases, cooperative societies find it advantageous to form [[co-operative federation]]s in which all of the members are themselves cooperatives. Historically, these have predominantly come in the form of cooperative wholesale societies, and cooperative unions.<ref name="gide">Gide, Charles; as translated from French by the Co-operative Reference Library, Dublin, "Consumers' Co-Operative Societies", Manchester: The Co-Operative Union Limited, 1921, p. 122</ref> Cooperative federations are a means through which cooperative societies can fulfill the sixth [[Rochdale Principles|Rochdale Principle]], [[cooperation among cooperatives]], with the [[International Co-operative Alliance|ICA]] noting that "Co-operatives serve their members most effectively and strengthen the co-operative movement by working together through local, national, regional and international structures."<ref name="ica-statistics">[http://www.ica.coop/coop/statistics.html Statistical information on the Co-operative Movement<!--Bot-generated title-->]</ref> |
|||
{{See also|List of Co-operative Federations}} |
|||
====Cooperative wholesale society==== |
|||
{{Main|Co-operative wholesale society}} |
|||
According to cooperative economist [[Charles Gide]], the aim of a cooperative wholesale society is to arrange “bulk purchases, and, if possible, organise production.”<ref name="gide"/> The best historical example of this were the English CWS and the Scottish CWS, which were the forerunners to the modern [[The Co-operative Group|Co-operative Group]]. |
|||
====Cooperative Union==== |
|||
{{Main|Co-operative union}} |
|||
A second common form of co-operative federation is a co-operative union, whose objective (according to Gide) is “to develop the spirit of solidarity among societies and... in a word, to exercise the functions of a government whose authority, it is needless to say, is purely moral.”<ref name="gide"/> [[Co-operatives UK]] and the [[International Co-operative Alliance]] are examples of such arrangements. |
|||
====Co-operative party==== |
|||
<span id="Co-operative Party" /> |
|||
In some countries with a strong cooperative sector, such as the UK, cooperatives may find it advantageous to form a parliamentary [[political party]] to represent their interests. The British [[Co-operative Party]] and the Canadian [[Co-operative Commonwealth Federation]] are prime examples of such arrangements. |
|||
The [[British co-operative movement|British cooperative movement]] formed the Co-operative Party in the early 20th century to represent members of [[consumers' cooperative]]s in Parliament. The Co-operative Party now has a permanent electoral pact with the [[Labour Party (UK)|Labour Party]], and has 29 members of parliament who were elected at the [[United Kingdom general election, 2005|2005 general election]] as [[Labour Co-operative]] [[Member of Parliament|MPs]]. UK cooperatives retain a significant market share in [[Co-op (supermarket)|food retail]], insurance, banking, funeral services, and the travel industry in many parts of the country. |
|||
==See also== |
|||
{{Portal box|Cooperatives|Organized labour}} |
|||
{{div col|3}} |
|||
*[[Co-operative economics]] |
|||
*[[Co-operative living arrangements]] |
|||
*[[Collective]] |
|||
*[[Common ownership]] |
|||
*[[Commune (intentional community)]] |
|||
*[[Cost the limit of price]] |
|||
*[[Danish cooperative movement]] |
|||
*[[Democratic socialism]] |
|||
*[[Employee-owned corporation]] |
|||
*[[Friendly Society]] |
|||
*[[History of the cooperative movement]] |
|||
*[[Industrial and provident society]] |
|||
*[[List of Co-operative Federations]] |
|||
*[[List of cooperatives]] |
|||
*[[Microfinance]] / [[microcredit]] |
|||
*[[Mondragón Cooperative Corporation]] |
|||
*[[Mutual aid (politics)|mutual aid]] |
|||
*[[Mutual organization]] |
|||
*[[Mutual Ownership Defense Housing Division]] |
|||
*[[Mutualism (economic theory)]] |
|||
*[[Neo-Capitalism]] |
|||
*[[Participatory democracy]] |
|||
*[[Participatory economics]] |
|||
*[[Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen]] |
|||
*[[Rochdale Principles]] |
|||
*[[Social economy]] |
|||
*[[Social enterprise]] |
|||
*[[Syndicalism]] |
|||
*[[Socialism]] |
|||
{{div col end}} |
|||
==Notes== |
|||
{{Reflist}} |
|||
30. Llewellyn, D. and Holmes, M. (1991) 'In Defence of Mutuality: A Redress to an Emerging |
|||
Conventional Wisdom', |
|||
Annals of Public and Co-operative Economics, Vol.62(3): pp. 319–354 (p. 327). |
|||
31. Armitage, S. (1991) 'Consequences of Mutual Ownership for Building Societies', |
|||
The Service Industries Journal, October, Vol.11(4): pp. 458–480 (p. 471). |
|||
32. Rasmusen, E. (1988) 'Mutual banks and stock banks', |
|||
Journal of Law and Economics, October, Vol.31: pp. 395–421 (p. 412). |
|||
33. Masulis, R. (1987) 'Changes in Ownership Structure: Conversions of Mutual Savings and |
|||
Loans to Stock Charter', |
|||
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.18: pp. 29–59 (p. 32). |
|||
==References== |
|||
{{Refbegin}} |
|||
*{{Cite journal|author=Japanese Consumers' Co-operative Union |title=co.op, 2003 Facts and Figures |year=2003 |url=http://www.co-op.or.jp/jccu/English_here/publications/ff/ff2003.pdf}}{{Dead link|date=July 2010}} |
|||
*{{Cite journal|author=Isao Takamura |title=Japan: Consumer Co-op Movement in Japan |year=1995 |url=http://uwcc.wisc.edu/icic/today/consumer/move.html}} |
|||
{{Refend}} |
|||
==Further reading== |
|||
*[http://backspace.com/notes/2005/09/collectives-for-designers.php "Consider the Collective: More than business as usual"] by John Emerson, 2005. Article on graphic design and printing cooperatives. |
|||
*"Consumer Co-operatives in a Changing World" edited by Johann Brazda and Robert Schediwy (ICA), 1989 |
|||
*[http://fax.libs.uga.edu/HD3271xG453/ ''Consumers' Co-operative Societies''], by [[Charles Gide]], 1922 |
|||
*[http://fax.libs.uga.edu/HD2951xC776/ ''Co-operation 1921-1947''], published monthly by the [[Cooperative League of America]] |
|||
*[http://abob.libs.uga.edu/bobk/coopp.html ''Cooperative Peace''], by [[James Peter Warbasse]], 1950 |
|||
*[http://www.uwcc.wisc.edu/info/uwcc_pubs/primer.html ''Cooperatives: Principles and practices in the 21st century''], by Kimberly A. Zeuli and Robert Cropp, 2004 |
|||
*[http://fax.libs.uga.edu/HD2965xW37/ ''Problems Of Cooperation''], by James Peter Warbasse, 1941 |
|||
*[http://fax.libs.uga.edu/HD3486xH7/ ''The History of Co-operation''], by [[George Jacob Holyoake]], 1908 |
|||
*"''For All The People: Uncovering the Hidden History of Cooperation, Cooperative Movements, and Communalism in America''," PM Press, by John Curl, 2009 |
|||
*"The International Co-operative Movement" by Johnston Birchall, 1997 |
|||
*[http://digitalcommons.shu.ac.uk/ciod_papers/57/ ''Cooperative Social Enterprises: Company Rules, Access to Finance and Management Practice'' in the ''Social Enterprise Journal'', Vol. 5., Issue, 1] by Rory Ridley-Duff, 2009. |
|||
*''Developing Successful Worker Co-ops'', London: Sage Publications by Cornforth, C. J., Thomas, A., Spear, R. G. & Lewis, J. M., 1988. |
|||
*''Reluctant Entrepreneurs'', Open University Press by Paton, R., 1989. |
|||
*''Making Mondragon'', New York: ILR Press/Itchaca, by Whyte, W. F. & Whyte, K. K., 1991 |
|||
*[http://cooperativenetwork.coop/wm/education/youthprograms/web/USDACurriculum_MNedition/usdamnedition.html ''Understanding Cooperatives''], a curriculum on cooperative business for secondary school students. |
|||
==External links== |
|||
{{Wikisource1911Enc|co-operation}} |
|||
{{Commons category|Cooperatives}} |
|||
*[http://www.CoopsCanada.coop/ Canadian Co-operative Association] |
|||
*[http://www.uk.coop/ Co-operatives UK] |
|||
*[http://www.debut-brussels.com/ DEBUuT, Business Cooperative of the Brussels Region] |
|||
*[http://www.ica.coop/ International Co-operative Alliance] |
|||
*[http://www.cibp.eu/ International Confederation of Popular Banks] |
|||
*[http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2006/0706bowmanstone.html Venezuela's Cooperative Revolution] from [[Dollars & Sense]] magazine |
|||
*[http://archive.co-op.ac.uk/ The National Co-operative Archive] – holds records relating to all aspects of the co-operative movement. |
|||
*[http://www.credit-coops.ru/ The European Union Project “Credit Cooperatives - Russian Federation”] official web site |
|||
*[http://www.communitiesconference.org/ Twin Oaks Communities Conference] Conference focused on education about Cooperative Living |
|||
{{Template group |
|||
|list = |
|||
{{Co-operatives |state=uncollapsed}} |
|||
{{Anarchism}} |
|||
}} |
|||
{{Use dmy dates|date=September 2010}} |
|||
[[Category:Cooperatives| ]] |
|||
[[Category:Types of organization]] |
|||
[[Category:Types of companies]] |
|||
[[Category:Business models]] |
|||
[[Category:Social economy]] |
|||
[[Category:Mutualism]] |
|||
[[als:Genossenschaft]] |
|||
[[br:Kevelouri]] |
|||
[[bg:Кооперация]] |
|||
[[ca:Cooperativa]] |
|||
[[cs:Družstvo]] |
|||
[[da:Kooperativ]] |
|||
[[de:Genossenschaft]] |
|||
[[es:Cooperativa]] |
|||
[[eo:Kooperativo]] |
|||
[[eu:Kooperatiba]] |
|||
[[fa:شرکت تعاونی]] |
|||
[[fr:Coopérative]] |
|||
[[fy:Koöperaasje]] |
|||
[[gl:Cooperativa]] |
|||
[[ko:생활협동조합]] |
|||
[[hr:Zadruga]] |
|||
[[id:Koperasi]] |
|||
[[ia:Cooperative]] |
|||
[[it:Società cooperativa]] |
|||
[[he:קואופרטיב]] |
|||
[[la:Societas cooperativa]] |
|||
[[lt:Kooperatyvas]] |
|||
[[hu:Szövetkezet]] |
|||
[[nl:Coöperatie]] |
|||
[[ja:生活協同組合]] |
|||
[[no:Samvirke]] |
|||
[[nn:Samvirkelag]] |
|||
[[pl:Spółdzielnia]] |
|||
[[pt:Cooperativismo]] |
|||
[[ru:Кооператив]] |
|||
[[sk:Družstvo (ekonómia)]] |
|||
[[fi:Osuuskunta]] |
|||
[[sv:Kooperativ]] |
|||
[[te:సహకార సంఘాలు]] |
|||
[[th:สหกรณ์]] |
|||
[[tr:Kooperatif]] |
[[tr:Kooperatif]] |
||
[[uk:Кооператив]] |
[[uk:Кооператив]] |
Revision as of 10:44, 24 November 2010
A cooperative (also co-operative; often referred to as a co-op) is a business organization owned and operated by a group of individuals for their mutual benefit.<ref>{{Cite book |