Jump to content

Girsanov theorem

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Kaslanidi (talk | contribs) at 18:52, 30 December 2009 (→‎External links). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

Visualisation of the Girsanov theorem — The left side shows a Wiener process with negative drift under a canonical measure P; on the right side each path of the process is colored according to its likelihood under the martingale measure Q. The density transformation from P to Q is given by the Girsanov theorem.

In probability theory, the Girsanov theorem tells how stochastic processes change under changes in measure. The theorem is especially important in the theory of financial mathematics as it tells how to convert from the physical measure which describes the probability that an underlying instrument (such as a share price or interest rate) will take a particular value or values to the risk-neutral measure which is a very useful tool for evaluating the value of derivatives on the underlying.

History

Results of this type were first proved by Cameron–Martin in the 1940s and by Girsanov in 1960. They have been subsequently extended to more general classes of process culminating in the general form of Lenglart (1977).

Significance

Girsanov's theorem is important in the general theory of stochastic processes since it enables the key result that if Q is a measure absolutely continuous with respect to P then every P-semimartingale is a Q-semimartingale.

Statement of theorem

We state the theorem first for the special case when the underlying stochastic process is a Wiener process. This special case is sufficient for risk-neutral pricing in the Black-Scholes model and in many other models (eg all continuous models).

Let be a Wiener process on the Wiener probability space . Let be a measurable process adapted to the natural filtration of the Wiener process .

Given an adapted process define

where is the stochastic exponential (or Doléans exponential) of X with respect to W, i.e.

If is a martingale then a probability measure Q can be defined on such that we have Radon–Nikodym derivative

Then for each t the measure Q restricted to the unaugmented sigma fields is equivalent to P restricted to

Furthermore if Y is a local martingale under P then the process

is a Q local martingale on the filtered probability space .

Corollary

If X is a continuous process and W is Brownian Motion under measure P then

is Brownian motion under Q.

The fact that is continuous is trivial; by Girsanov's theorem it is a Q local martingale, and by computing

it follows by Levy's characterization of Brownian Motion that this is a Q Brownian Motion.

Comments

In many common applications, the process X is defined by

For X of this form then a sufficient condition for to be a martingale is Novikov's condition which requires that

The stochastic exponential is the process Z which solves the stochastic differential equation

The measure Q constructed above is not equivalent to P on as this would only be the case if the Radon–Nikodym derivative were a uniformly integrable martingale, which the exponential martingale described above is not (for ).

Application to finance

This theorem can be used to show the Black-Scholes model under the unique risk neutral measure, i.e. the measure in which the fair value of a derivative is the discounted expected value, Q, is specified by

See also

References

  • C. Dellacherie and P.-A. Meyer, "Probabilités et potentiel -- Théorie de Martingales" Chapitre VII, Hermann 1980
  • E. Lenglart "Transformation de martingales locales par changement absolue continu de probabilités", Zeitschrift für Wahrscheinlichkeit 39 (1977) pp 65-70.