Jump to content

Braess's paradox

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Quest for Truth (talk | contribs) at 21:03, 7 June 2012 (How far from optimal is traffic at equilibrium). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

Braess's paradox, credited to the mathematician Dietrich Braess, states that adding extra capacity to a network when the moving entities selfishly choose their route, can in some cases reduce overall performance. This is because the Nash equilibrium of such a system is not necessarily optimal.

The paradox is stated as follows: "For each point of a road network, let there be given the number of cars starting from it, and the destination of the cars. Under these conditions one wishes to estimate the distribution of traffic flow. Whether one street is preferable to another depends not only on the quality of the road, but also on the density of the flow. If every driver takes the path that looks most favorable to him, the resultant running times need not be minimal. Furthermore, it is indicated by an example that an extension of the road network may cause a redistribution of the traffic that results in longer individual running times."

The reason for this is that in a Nash equilibrium, drivers have no incentive to change their routes. If the system is not in a Nash equilibrium, selfish drivers must be able to improve their respective travel times by changing the routes they take. In the case of Braess's paradox, drivers will continue to switch until they reach Nash equilibrium, despite the reduction in overall performance.

If the latency functions are linear then adding an edge can never make total travel time at equilibrium worse by a factor of more than 4/3.[1]

Example

Consider a road network as shown in the adjacent diagram, on which 4000 drivers wish to travel from point Start to End. The travel time in minutes on the Start-A road is the number of travelers (T) divided by 100, and on Start-B is a constant 45 minutes (likewise with the roads across from them). If the dashed road does not exist (so the traffic network has 4 roads in total), the time needed to drive Start-A-End route with A drivers would be . And the time needed to drive the Start-B-End route with B drivers would be . If either route were shorter, it would not be a Nash equilibrium: a rational driver would switch routes from the longer route to the shorter route. As there are 4000 drivers, the fact that can be used to derive the fact that when the system is at equilibrium. Therefore, each route takes minutes.

Now suppose the dashed line is a road with an extremely short travel time of approximately 0 minutes. In this situation, all drivers will choose the Start-A route rather than the Start-B route, because Start-A will only take minutes at its worst, whereas Start-B is guaranteed to take 45 minutes. Once at point A, every rational driver will elect to take the "free" road to B and from there continue to End, because once again A-End is guaranteed to take 45 minutes while A-B-End will take at most minutes. Each driver's travel time is minutes, an increase from the 65 minutes required when the fast A-B road did not exist. No driver has an incentive to switch, as the two original routes (Start-A-End and Start-B-End) are both now 85 minutes. If every driver were to agree not to use the A-B path, every driver would benefit by reducing their travel time by 15 minutes. However, because any single driver will always benefit by taking the A-B path, the socially optimal distribution is not stable and so Braess's paradox occurs.

Existence of an equilibrium

Let be the formula for the cost of people driving along edge . If a traffic graph has linear edges (those of the form where and are constants) then an equilibrium will always exist.

Suppose we have a linear traffic graph with people driving along edge . Let the energy of e, be

(If let ). Let the total energy of the traffic graph be the sum of the energies of every edge in the graph.

Suppose that the distribution for the traffic graph is not an equilibrium. There must be at least one driver who can switch their route and improve total travel time. Suppose their original route is while their new route is . Let be total energy of the traffic graph, and consider what happens when the route is removed. The energy of each edge will be reduced by and so the will be reduced by . Note that this is simply the total travel time needed to take the original route. If we then add the new route, , will be increased by the total travel time needed to take the new route. Because the new route is shorter than the original route, must decrease. If we repeat this process, will continue to decrease. As must remain positive, eventually an equilibrium must occur.

Finding an equilibrium

The above proof outlines a procedure known as Best Response Dynamics, which finds an equilibrium for a linear traffic graph and terminates in a finite number of steps. The algorithm is termed "best response" because at each step of the algorithm, if the graph is not at equilibrium then some driver has a best response to the strategies of all other drivers, and switches to that response.

Pseudocode for Best Response Dynamics:

 Let P be some traffic pattern.
 while P is not at equilibrium:
   compute the potential energy e of P
   for each driver d in P:
     for each alternate path p available to d:
        compute the potential energy n of the pattern when d takes path p
        if n < e:
          modify P so that d takes path p
          continue the topmost while

At each step, if some particular driver could do better by taking an alternate path (a "best response"), doing so strictly decreases the energy of the graph. If no driver has a best response, the graph is at equilibrium. Since the energy of the graph strictly decreases with each step, the Best Response Dynamics algorithm must eventually halt.

How far from optimal is traffic at equilibrium

At worst, traffic in equilibrium is twice as bad as socially optimal[1]

Proof

= starting point for car j

= target for car j

Strategies for car j are possible paths from to

Each edge e has a travel function for some

Energy on edge e with x drivers:

Total time spent by all drivers on that edge:

((where there are x terms))

E(e) is less than or equal to T(e)

Resulting Inequality

If Z is a traffic pattern:

If we start from a socially optimal traffic pattern Z and end in an equilibrium pattern Z':

Thus we can see that worst is twice as bad as optimal.

How rare is Braess's paradox?

In 1983 Steinberg and Zangwill provided, under reasonable assumptions, necessary and sufficient conditions for Braess's paradox to occur in a general transportation network when a new route is added. (Note that their result applies to the addition of any new route — not just to the case of adding a single link.) As a corollary, they obtain that Braess's paradox is about as likely to occur as not occur; their result applies to random rather than planned networks and additions. In Seoul, South Korea, a speeding-up in traffic around the city was seen when a motorway was removed as part of the Cheonggyecheon restoration project.[2] In Stuttgart, Germany after investments into the road network in 1969, the traffic situation did not improve until a section of newly-built road was closed for traffic again.[3] In 1990 the closing of 42nd street in New York City reduced the amount of congestion in the area.[4] In 2008 Youn, Gastner and Jeong demonstrated specific routes in Boston, New York City and London where this might actually occur and pointed out roads that could be closed to reduce predicted travel times.[5]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b von Ahn L (2008-10-02). "Modeling Network Traffic Using Game Theory" (PDF). Science of the Web: Lecture 10. Carnegie Mellon University. Retrieved 2008-11-16.
  2. ^ Easley, D and Kleinberg, J: "Networks", page 71. Cornell Store Press, 2008
  3. ^ Knödel W (1969). Graphentheoretische Methoden und ihre Anwendungen. Springer-Verlag. pp. 57–9. ISBN 978-3-540-04668-4.
  4. ^ Kolata, Gina (1990-12-25). "What if They Closed 42d Street and Nobody Noticed?". New York Times. Retrieved 2008-11-16.
  5. ^ Youn H, Gastner MT, Jeong H (2008). "Price of anarchy in transportation networks: efficiency and optimality control". Phys. Rev. Lett. 101 (12): 128701. arXiv:0712.1598. Bibcode:2008PhRvL.101l8701Y. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.101.128701. PMID 18851419. {{cite journal}}: Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)

Further reading

  • D. Braess, Über ein Paradoxon aus der Verkehrsplanung. Unternehmensforschung 12, 258–268 (1969) [1] [2]
  • Katharina Belaga-Werbitzky: „Das Paradoxon von Braess in erweiterten Wheatstone-Netzen mit M/M/1-Bedienern“ ISBN 3-89959-123-2
  • Translation of the Braess 1968 article from German to English appears as the article "On a paradox of traffic planning," by D. Braess, A. Nagurney, and T. Wakolbinger in the journal Transportation Science, volume 39, 2005, pp. 446–450. More information
  • A. D. Irvine. How Braess's Paradox Solves Newcomb's Problem. International Studies in Philosophy of Science, Vol. 7 (1993), no. 2, 145–164.
  • R. Steinberg and W.I. Zangwill. The Prevalence of Braess's Paradox. Transportation Science, Vol. 17 (1983), no. 3, 301–318.
  • A. Rapoport, T. Kugler, S. Dugar, and E. J. Gisches, Choice of routes in congested traffic networks: Experimental tests of the Braess Paradox. Games and Economic Behavior 65 (2009) [3]
  • T. Roughgarden. "The Price of Anarchy." MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2005.

Template:Link GA