Greenwood–Hercowitz–Huffman preferences
Greenwood–Hercowitz–Huffman preferences are a particular functional form of utility developed by Jeremy Greenwood, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory Huffman, in their 1988 paper Investment, Capacity Utilization, and the Real Business Cycle.[1] It describes the macroeconomic impact of technological changes that affect the productivity of new capital goods. The paper also introduced the notions of investment-specific technological progress and capacity utilization into modern macroeconomics.
GHH preferences have Gorman form.
Often macroeconomic models assume that agents' utility is additively separable in consumption and labor. I.e., frequently the period utility function is something like
where is consumption and is labor (e.g., hours worked). Note that this is separable in that the utility (loss) from working does not directly affect the utility (gain or loss) from consumption, i.e. the cross-derivative of utility with respect to consumption and labor is 0.
GHH preferences might instead have a form like:
where now consumption and labor are not additively separable in the same way. For an agent with this utility function, the amount she/he works will actually affect the amount of utility she/he receives from consumption, i.e. the cross-derivative of utility with respect to consumption and labor is unequal to 0.
More generally, the preferences are of the form
The first order condition of with respect is given by
which implies
As is typically just a wage , this means the labor choice is a function of only the wage and has a closed form with . As a result, the preferences are exceptionally convenient to work with. Moreover, as the marginal rate of substitution is independent of consumption and only depends on the real wage, there is no wealth effect on the labor supply. Using preference without a wealth effect on the labor supply might help to explain the aggregate economic behavior following news shocks,[2] and government spending shocks.[3] Their use is also very common in open macro studies.[4]
Generalization: Jaimovich–Rebelo preferences
[edit]GHH preferences are not consistent with a balanced growth path. Jaimovich and Rebelo proposed a preference specification that allows scaling the short-run wealth effect on the labor supply.[5] The two polar cases are the standard King–Plosser–Rebelo preferences[6] and the GHH-preferences.
References
[edit]- Jeremy Greenwood, Zvi Hercowitz and Gregory W. Huffman (1988) "Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle" (Jeremy Greenwood's website) American Economic Review 78 (3): 402–17.
- Notes
- ^ An archive for the original research is here: http://hdl.handle.net/1802/2688
- ^ Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie; Uribe, Martin (2010). "What's news in business cycles?" (PDF).
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ^ Monacelli, Tommaso; Perotti, Roberto (2008). "Fiscal policy, wealth effects, and markups" (PDF).
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ^ Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie; Uribe, Martin (2003). "Closing Small Open Economy Models". Journal of International Economics. 61: 163–185. doi:10.1016/S0022-1996(02)00056-9. hdl:10419/79190.
- ^ Jaimovich, Nir; Rebelo, Sergio (2009). "Can news about the future drive the business cycle?". American Economic Review. 99 (4): 1097–1118. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.172.1551. doi:10.1257/aer.99.4.1097. S2CID 8238010.
- ^ King, Robert G.; Plosser, Charles I.; Rebelo, Sergio T. (2002). "Production, Growth and Business Cycles: Technical Appendix". Computational Economics. 20 (1–2): 87–116. doi:10.1023/A:1020529028761. S2CID 62057301.