The Chicago Plan Revisited
The Chicago Plan Revisited is an International Monetary Fund (IMF) report from 2012 by Jaromir Benes and Michael Kumhof. The focus of the study is the so-called Chicago plan of the 1930s which the authors have updated to fit into today's economy. The basic idea is that banks should be required to have full coverage for money they lend; this is called 100% reserve banking, instead of currently prevalent system of fractional reserve banking. Under this proposal, banks would no longer be allowed to create new money in the form of credit in connection with their lending activities. Instead, the central bank should be solely responsible for all the creation of all forms of money, not just paper money and coins. The advantages of such a system, according to the authors, are a more balanced economy without the booms and busts of the current system, the elimination of bank runs, and a drastic reduction of both public and private debt. The authors rely on both economic theory and historical examples, and state that inflation, according to their calculations, would be very low.
Background
Following the great crash of 1929, a severe economic depression spread all over the world, not least in the USA, and, in the midst of it, a radical monetary reform called the Chicago Plan was published. The plan earned its name from the fact that it was thought out by economists at the University of Chicago and it was published in a number of editions in 1933-1935. The first plan, only six pages long, was published March 16, 1933 and was supported by a number of leading economists. By the end of that year, another version, augmented by comments on the original version, was published, and over the next two years more editions with minor changes followed.
The new Chicago Plan
The Chicago Plan Revisited features, apart from an introduction and summary, five chapters: a historical background including a description of the original Chicago Model, an analysis of the current model, an outline of the consequences for banks, households, industry and government, a chapter on calibrations and one about the credit cycles. A few key features of the exposition are:
History
The chapter begins by questioning the standard description of the origin of money, in brief, that man first engaged in barter and then introduced money as a means of simplifying the trade and making it more efficient. On the contrary, according to the authors, anthropological and historical studies have shown that barter was practically non-existent in earlier times. The authors assert that when something resembling a monetary system was introduced, it took the form of various credit systems in which credits were denominated in livestock, tools, seeds and other items. When, only much later, a genuine monetary system was introduced, it was to satisfy state, religious and social or ceremonial needs and not for private reasons of simplifying trade. This, as the authors emphasize, is not only of academic interest, as the discussion on the origin of money leads directly to the question of the nature of money and who should be authorized to create money. More specifically, the standard description of the origin of money since Adam Smith has been used as a motive for the private issuance and control of money.
Fisher's argument
Like Irving Fisher, who was a leading proponent of the first Chicago Plan, the authors are looking upon four great advantages in state controlled issuance of money compared with the private money creating activity of the banks. The first is increased control with the fluctuations of the market so that exaggerated booms and slumps are prevented. The second advantage is increased financial stability due to the likely elimination of the risk of bank runs. The third and fourth advantages put forward by the authors are a dramatic reduction of public debt together with a great potential for minimizing private debt.
The transformation
The most important feature of the new model is that the banks would be obliged to back up deposits 100 percent with credits issued by the government. This means that they would not be allowed to create their own new credits which, in turn, are made into deposits. The transformation into this system, which would mean that the government would be in exclusive control of the aggregated credit volume and the total amount of money, would take place in two steps. In the first step, the banks would be forced to borrow from the Treasury to obtain full coverage for all deposits, meaning that all the banks' private and corporal statements of accounts would have to be equalled by a corresponding amount of available money.
This government credit, which is an asset for the government and a debt for the banks, would, from a government perspective, be used for redeeming the interest-bearing government bonds that the banks own (and which is an asset for them). In the next step, the banks would credit the government credit as well as the assets from private deposits and holdings of government bonds. In other words, the debt owed to the government would be cancelled out by assets from deposits and governments bonds. In this way, the national debt owned by the private sector would be eliminated and all deposits, which today lack backing, would be fully backed up. Proponents argue that all this would be possible with the aforementioned government credit. The process would be concluded by the banks adapting to a lower official cash demand by lowering the amount of their own capital.[1]
Reactions
Economists at the Paris School of Economics have commented on the plan, stating that it is already the status quo for coinage currency,[2] and a Norges Bank economist has examined the proposal in the context of considering the finance industry as part of the real economy.[3]
Positive
In The Telegraph, one of England's major newspapers, Ambrose Evans-Pritchard described the report in positive terms. The article deals with both the historical as well as other arguments. In addition, it is mentioned that two of the most prominent economists of the 20th century, Henry Simons and Irving Fisher, were the fathers of the original Chicago Plan, and they consider Richard Werner a contemporary economist with basically the same agenda. Stuart Jeanne Bramhall, a writer at the Open Salon, regards the section on economic history as the most interesting, for example that it is a myth that money is developed from physical objects with intrinsic value, say gold, into today's 'fiat money', the reason being that fiat money, which is characterized by the fact that the value is determined by law, has been used for thousands of years. In this context, she is referring to the Athenian leader Solon, whose debt write-offs in 599 B.C. are described as the first known Chicago Plan. She concludes by noting that the movement to eradicating the debt-based monetary system is still considered radical, but the fact that an IMF study now positions itself to the radical side, suggests that the global crisis is much greater than our governments and mainstream media are willing to acknowledge and also that people in high positions know that the decision makers basically are lacking alternatives.[4]
Matthew C. Klein of Bloomberg's The Ticker agreed with James Tobin that "the current marriage between deposit-taking and credit creation was itself a historical accident -- and it's a union that hasn't worked out so well."[5][6] In Sweden, Andreas Cervenka, a Svenska Dagbladet columnist, describes the proposal that 'the state is taking over the creation of money' as pure dynamite. In his view, it is unlikely that such a system will be introduced in the near future, but he also sees the report as a confirmation that we live in 'a time when most aspects of the economic system can and will be questioned'.[7] A Centre for Economic Policy Research paper agrees with the conclusion that, "no real liability is created by new fiat money creation, and therefore public debt does not rise as a result."[8]
Negative
Criticism of the report has emerged too, not least from commentators associated with the Austrian School. Gary North, for instance, who earlier had engaged in a furious debate with Ellen Brown and other so-called 'greenbackers', holds, to put it briefly, that proposals such as this one would not work because it would amount to the same as handing over the money fountain to the state which he believes would invariably lead to inflation or hyperinflation. According to North, it is just as bad to let the state, or the central bank in alliance with the state, 'create money out of air' as it is to let the banks do it through their fractional reserve banking. The only right thing to do would be to let the market take care of the creation of money, with a gold standard, but without fractional reserve banking. Martin Sibileau, who is also an Austrian economist, considers the idea of letting the state buy the banks' assets, in the form of deposits, a kind of confiscation. He believes that the credit can not be created unilaterally by one party, but that it requires two parties, in mutual agreement, creating it together. Moreover, depositors and shareholders, would, in the event that the reform were introduced, understand that the assets had been priced according to this 'government credit', and they would try to escape from this by selling assets, in other words the government credit, at a loss for real money, that is, cash.
The Iceland Plan
Recently, advisors to the government of Iceland have come up with a plan for monetary reform based on the Chicago Plan, but also incorporating several elements from other developments. The plan centers on the idea of replacing the current system of private creation of money by banks by a system where only the government is authorized to issue "Sovereign Money". See Sigurjonsson, Frosti (March 2015) Monetary Reform – A Better Monetary System for Iceland, report commissioned by Prime Minister of Iceland, Reykjavik, Iceland.
The Swiss referendum
Switzerland will hold a referendum in 2016 on the initiative that would prohibit commercial banks from creating money. [9]
See also
References
- ^ Sibileau, Martin Why the Chicago Plan is flawed reasoning and would fail (read 8th of January 2013)
- ^ "Debt-Deflation versus the Liquidity Trap: the Dilemma of Nonconventional Monetary Policy" CNRS, CES, Paris School of Economics, ESCP-Europe, October 23, 2012
- ^ "Credit and debt in Economic Theory: Which Way forward?" “Economics of Credit and Debt workshop, November 2012
- ^ Bramhall, Stuart Jeanne The IMF Proposal to Strip Banks of Their Power (read January 9th 2013)
- ^ Klein, Matthew C. (March 27, 2013). "The Best Way to Save Banking Is to Kill It". Bloomberg. Retrieved 2 April 2013.
- ^ Tobin, James (Nov–Dec 1987). "A Case for Preserving Regulatory Distinctions" (PDF). Challenge. 30 (5): 10–17. Retrieved 2 April 2013.
- ^ Cervenka, Andreas En lösning på skuldkrisen? Published November 5th 2012 on blog.svd.se/cervenkaspengar (read January 7th 2013)
- ^ "The economic crisis: How to stimulate economies without increasing public debt", Centre for Economic Policy Research, August 2012
- ^ [1]
External links
- The Chicago Plan Revisited - online
- Why the Chicago plan is flawed reasoning and would fail - a critical analyse by Martin Sibileau, published November 11, 2012
- Phillips, Ronnie J. The ‘Chicago Plan’ and New Deal Banking Reform
- A public lesson, published on YouTube