Jump to content

Vickrey auction

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by 82.24.167.44 (talk) at 13:11, 8 May 2007 (Removed self-referential 'Vickrey-Clarke-Groves' link). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

A Vickrey auction is a type of sealed-bid auction, where bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins, but the price paid is the second highest bid. The auction was created by William Vickrey. This type of auction is strategically similar to an English auction, and gives bidders an incentive to bid their true value.

Vickrey's original paper considered only auctions where a single, indivisible good is being sold. In this case, the terms Vickrey auction and second-price sealed-bid auction are equivalent, and are used interchangeably. When multiple identical units (or a divisible good) are being sold in a single auction, the most obvious generalization is to have all bidders pay the amount of the highest non-winning bid. This is known as a uniform-price auction. The uniform-price auction does not, however, result in bidders bidding their true valuations as they do in a second-price auction unless each bidder only has demand for a single unit.

A generalization of the Vickrey auction that maintains the incentive to bid truthfully is known as the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG) mechanism. The idea in VCG is that each player in the auction pays the opportunity cost that their presence introduces to all the other players. For example, suppose that we want to auction two apples, and we have three bidders. Bidder A wants one apple and bids $5 for that apple. Bidder B wants one apple and is willing to pay $2 for it. Bidder C wants two apples and is willing to pay $6 to have both of them, but is uninterested in buying only one without the other. First, we decide the outcome of the auction by maximizing bids: the apples go to bidder A and bidder B. Next, to decide payments, we consider the opportunity cost that each bidder imposed on the rest of the bidders. Currently, B has a utility of $2. If bidder A had not been present, C would have won, and had a utility of $6, so A pays $6-$2 = $4. For the payment of bidder B: currently A has a utility of $5 and C has a utility of 0. If bidder B had been absent, C would have won and had a utility of $6, so B pays $6-$5 = $1. The outcome is identical whether or not bidder C participates, so C does not need to pay anything.

Vickrey auctions are much studied in economic literature, but are not particularly common in practice. One market in which they have been used is stamp collecting. eBay's system of proxy bidding is similar, but not identical, to a Vickrey auction. A slight generalized variant of a Vickrey auction, named generalized second-price auction, which is different from the VCG mechanism, is known to be used in Google's and Yahoo!'s online advertisement programmes.[1]

Properties

Self-revelation/Incentive compatibility

In a Vickrey auction with independent private values (IPV) each bidder maximizes his or her expected utility by bidding (revealing) his or her true valuation.

Ex-post efficiency

A Vickrey auction is ex-post efficient (the winner is the bidder with the highest valuation) under the most general circumstances; it thus provides a baseline model against which the efficiency properties of other types of auctions can be posited.

Weaknesses

Despite the Vickrey auction's strengths, it has shortcomings:

  • The auction is not budget balanced. It does not maximize the seller revenues; the seller revenues may even be zero in VCG auctions. If the purpose of holding the auction is to maximize profit for the seller, as is often the case, the Vickrey auction is a poor choice.
  • It does not allow for Price discovery, that is, discovery of the market price if the buyers are unsure of their own valuations, without sequential auctions.
  • Sellers may use shill bids to increase profit.
  • In iterated Vickrey auctions, the strategy of revealing true valuations is no longer dominant.

The Vickrey-Clark-Groves mechanism has the additional shortcomings:

  • It is vulnerable to collusion by losing bidders.
  • It is vulnerable to shill bidding with respect to the buyers.
  • The seller's revenues are non-monotonic with regard to the sets of bidders and offers.

The non-monotonicity of seller's revenues can be shown by the following example. Consider 3 bidders A, B, and C, and two homogeneous items bid upon, Y and Z. A wants both items and bids $2 for the package of Y and Z. B and C both bid $2 each for a single item (bid $2 for Y or Z), as they really want one item but don't care if they have the second. Now, Y and Z are allocated to B and C, but the price is $0, as can be found by removing either B or C respectively. If C bid $0 instead of $2, then the seller would make $2 instead of $0. Because the seller's revenue can also go up when bids are increased, the seller's revenues are non-monotonic with respect to bids.

Use in U.S. Treasury Securities

U.S. Treasury securities are auctioned in competitive bidding under rules that are substantially identical to a Vickrey auction.

Use in Network Routing

In network routing, VCG mechanisms are a family of payment schemes based on the added value concept. The basic idea of a VCG mechanism in network routing is to pay the owner of each link or node (depending on the network model) its declared cost plus its added value. In many routing problems, this mechanism is not only strategyproof, but also the minimum among all strategyproof mechanisms.

In the simplest, unicast case, a least cost path in graph G is calculated based on the declared costs of each of the links, and payment is calculated as follows:

Each link on the LCP is paid

and each link not on the LCP is paid nothing. This routing problem is one of the cases for which VCG is strategyproof and minimum.

In 2004, it was shown that the expected VCG overpayment of an Erdös-Renyi random graph with nodes and edge probability approaches

as , approaches . Prior to this result, it was known that VCG overpayment in is

and

with high probability given

.

References

  • Vijay Krishna, Auction Theory
  • Peter Cramton, Yoav Shoham, Richard Steinberg (Eds), Combinatorial Auctions (2006), Chapter 1. ISBN 0-262-03342-9.

Notes

  1. ^ Benjamin Edelman, Michael Ostrovsky, and Michael Schwarz: "Internet Advertising and the Generalized Second-Price Auction: Selling Billions of Dollars Worth of Keywords". American Economic Review 97(1), 2007 pp 242-259.