Money creation: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Tag: references removed
Line 31: Line 31:
:the reference is found in the "Money Manager" section:
:the reference is found in the "Money Manager" section:
::"the Fed works to control money at its source by affecting the ability of financial institutions to "create" checkbook money through loans or investments. The control lever that the Fed uses in this process is the "reserves" that banks and thrifts must hold."</ref>
::"the Fed works to control money at its source by affecting the ability of financial institutions to "create" checkbook money through loans or investments. The control lever that the Fed uses in this process is the "reserves" that banks and thrifts must hold."</ref>
Dont stop, believeing hollddd o nt ot that feeeeeling

When a commercial bank loan is extended, new commercial bank money is created. As a loan is paid back, the commercial bank money disappears from existence.


===Re-lending===
===Re-lending===

Revision as of 22:34, 26 October 2009

Money creation is the process by which new money is produced or issued. Three ways to create money are; by manufacturing paper currency or metal coins, through debt and lending, and by government policies such as quantitative easing. The practices and regulation of production, issue and redemption of money are of central concern to monetary economics (e.g. money supply, monetarism), and affect the operation of financial markets and the purchasing power of money.

Central banks measure the money supply, which shows the amount of money in existence at a given time. An unknown portion of the new money created is indicated by comparing these measurements on various dates. For example in the US, one of the various money supply measurements, called M2, grew from $286,600,000,000 in January of 1959 to $8,327,000,000,000 in May 2009.[1]

The destruction of currency may occur when coins are scrapped to recover their precious metal content, which can be incentivized by the value of the metal coming to exceed the face value of the coin, or when the issuer redeems the securities.

Money creation by mints

Money created by manufacturing a new monetary unit, such as paper currency or metal coins, is bncbccbmarket, and manufacture it into coins that they use to pay for the bullion and their other production costs, and to provide a profit.

Nope

Under nationalized minting with a right to exchange

Nationalized minting means that the government has monopolized the business of minting coins, and the government operates mints that produce a national system of coinage. Under a metallic or bimetallic standard with a national mint, individuals normally have a right to bring precious metal to the national mint and to have it coined at a fixed discount. This discount is called seigniorage.

Basic economic analysis of this arrangement is that it makes the supply of coin elastic at the fixed price, however this fixed price is effectively a price control, and price control theory implies that the supply of coin would be more elastic (responsive) under competitive supply and no price controls.

Under nationalized minting with no right to exchange

Where there is no legal right to take metal to the national mint and to have it coined into a particular coin, the supply of the coin depends on government or mint policy. This can result in arbitrary debasement of coinage, where the government mint re-manufactures coin with a lower metallic value as a way to raise revenue. However it also enables some more complex coinage arrangements such as the composite legal tender system where gold coin was unlimited legal tender (produced under a right of exchange arrangement as above) and where silver coins are limited legal tender, and have a substantially reduced metallic value below their legal value, but are effectively redeemable at the mint for their legal value in gold coins. This makes the silver coins 'token' coins, and a form of financial asset (and a financial liability to the mint).

Money creation through the fractional reserve system

To avoid confusion, keep in mind that a "central bank" is not in any way a federal institution - it is a private bank, not unlike other private banks, except for the fact that it has the right to control the initial issuance of debt-backed monies to a central government. Almost all nations have central banks, and almost all of the world's money supply is controlled not by governments, but by private bankers. Fractional-reserve banking creates money whenever a new loan is created. In short, there are two types of money in a fractional-reserve banking system, the two types being legally equivalent [2][3]:

  1. central bank money (all money created by the central bank regardless of its form (banknotes, coins, electronic money through loans to private banks))
  2. commercial bank money (money created in the banking system through borrowing and lending) - sometimes referred to as checkbook money[4]

Dont stop, believeing hollddd o nt ot that feeeeeling

Re-lending

The mainstream economics theory of monetary creation is that commercial bank money is created by commercial banks re-lending central bank money: the central bank (an institution that can be charecterised as a partnership between the government and a private coorporation ) lends money to another commercial bank, which re-loans part of it, due to fractional reserves, and this portion is in turn itself re-lent (it is re-re-lent central bank money). This theory is disputed by some schools of heterodox economics, termed endogenous money, which instead argue that money is created endogenously by demand for credit and by commercial bank-initiated lending, rather than exogenously by central bank lending.

The table below displays how central bank money is used to produce commercial bank money via successive re-lending in this theory.

Fractional-Reserve Lending Cycled 10 times with a 20 percent reserve rate[5] [6][7][2]
individual bank amount deposited amount loaned out reserves
A 100 80 20
B 80 64 16
C 64 51.20 12.80
D 51.20 40.96 10.24
E 40.96 32.77 8.19
F 32.77 26.21 6.55
G 26.21 20.97 5.24
H 20.97 16.78 4.19
I 16.78 13.42 3.36
J 13.42 10.74 2.68
K 10.74




total reserves:



89.26

total amount deposited: total amount loaned out: total reserves + last amount deposited:

457.05 357.05 100





commercial bank money created + central bank money: commercial bank money created: central bank money:

457.05 357.05 100

Although no new money was physically created in addition to the initial $100 deposit, new commercial bank money is created through loans. The 2 boxes marked in red show the location of the original $100 deposit throughout the entire process. The total reserves plus the last deposit (or last loan, whichever is last) will always equal the original amount, which in this case is $100. As this process continues, more commercial bank money is created. For more information on how this system works, see Fractional-reserve banking.

An earlier form of such a table, featuring reinvestment from one period to the next and a geometric series, is found in the tableau économique of the Physiocrats, which is credited as the "first precise formulation" of such interdependent systems and the origin of multiplier theory.[8]

Money multiplier

The expansion of $100M through fractional-reserve lending at varying rates. Each curve approaches a limit. This limit is the value that the money multiplier calculates.

The most common mechanism used to measure this increase in the money supply is typically called the money multiplier. It calculates the maximum amount of money that an initial deposit can be expanded to with a given reserve ratio – such a factor is called a multiplier.

Formula

The money multiplier, m, is the inverse of the reserve requirement, R:

This formula stems from the fact that the sum of the "amount loaned out" column above can be expressed mathematically as a geometric series[9] with a common ratio of .

To correct for currency drain (a lessening of the impact of monetary policy due to peoples' desire to hold some currency in the form of cash) and for banks' desire to hold reserves in excess of the required amount, the formula

can be used, where Currency Drain is the percentage of money that people want to hold as cash and the Desired Reserve Ratio is the sum of the Required Reserve Ratio and the Excess Reserve Ratio.

Example

For example, with the reserve ratio of 20 percent, this reserve ratio, R, can also be expressed as a fraction:

So then the money multiplier, m, will be calculated as:

This number is multiplied by the initial deposit to show the maximum amount of money it can be expanded to[10].

Money creation through quantitative easing

Quantitative easing refers to the creation of a significant amount of new money (usually electronically) by a central bank. It is sometimes referred to as "printing money". This money is created to stimulate the economy, in particular to promote lending by banks. The central banks use the created money to buy up large quantities of securities from banks. This appears as deposits and gives the banks new money to lend. These securities could be government bonds, commercial loans, asset backed securities, or even stocks. Quantitative easing is usually used when lowering official interest rates is no longer effective because they are already close to or at zero.

Alternative theories

The above gives the mainstream economics theory of money creation. In heterodox economics, there are a number of alternative theories of how money is created, and generally emphasize endogenous money – that money is created by internal workings of an economy, rather than external forces – under whose rubric they thus fall. These theories include:

  • Chartalism, which holds that money is created by government deficit spending, and emphasizes (and advocates) fiat money.
  • Circuitist money theory, held by some post-Keynesians, which argues that money is created endogenously by the banking system, rather than exogenously by central bank lending. Further, they argue that money is not neutral – a credit money system is fundamentally different from a barter money system, and money and banks must be an integral part of economic models.
  • Credit Theory of Money This approach was founded by Joseph Schumpeter [11] A major proponent, who correctly warned about the pending Japanese banking crisis, [12] as well as the British banking crisis [13], is Southampton University Professor of International Banking, Richard Werner. His approach is characterised by the inductive research methodology (building theories not on axioms and assumptions, but empirical facts), the recognition of pervasive disequilibrium and hence quantity-rationing, the central role of banks as creators and allocators of the supply-determined money supply, and the disaggregation of credit into 'productive' credit creation (allowing non-inflationary growth even at full employment, in the presence of technological progress) and 'unproductive credit creation' (resulting in inflation of either the consumer or asset price variety).[14] Werner also points out that today many countries' central banks or financial regulators do not impose reserve requirements on banks, such as is the case in the United Kingdom. In this case, the textbook representation of fractional reserve banking becomes inapplicable. This, according to Werner, demonstrates that each bank has the power to create credit (and hence money); it is not a sequential process of banks lending their deposits, as textbooks say.

See also

External links

References

  1. ^ US Federal Reserve historical statistics June 11, 2009
  2. ^ a b Bank for International Settlements - The Role of Central Bank Money in Payment Systems. See page 9, titled, "The coexistence of central and commercial bank monies: multiple issuers, one currency": http://www.bis.org/publ/cpss55.pdf A quick quote in reference to the 2 different types of money is listed on page 3. It is the first sentence of the document:
    "Contemporary monetary systems are based on the mutually reinforcing roles of central bank money and commercial bank monies."
  3. ^ European Central Bank - Domestic payments in Euroland: commercial and central bank money: http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2000/html/sp001109_2.en.html One quote from the article referencing the two types of money:
    "At the beginning of the 20th almost the totality of retail payments were made in central bank money. Over time, this monopoly came to be shared with commercial banks, when deposits and their transfer via checks and giros became widely accepted. Banknotes and commercial bank money became fully interchangeable payment media that customers could use according to their needs. While transaction costs in commercial bank money were shrinking, cashless payment instruments became increasingly used, at the expense of banknotes"
  4. ^ Chicago Fed - Our Central Bank: http://www.chicagofed.org/consumer_information/the_fed_our_central_bank.cfm
    the reference is found in the "Money Manager" section:
    "the Fed works to control money at its source by affecting the ability of financial institutions to "create" checkbook money through loans or investments. The control lever that the Fed uses in this process is the "reserves" that banks and thrifts must hold."
  5. ^ Table created with the OpenOffice.org Calc spreadsheet program using data and information from the references listed.
  6. ^ Federal Reserve Education - How does the Fed Create Money?
    See the link to "The Principle of Multiple Deposit Creation" pdf document towards bottom of page.
  7. ^ Federal Reserve Bank of New York: An explanation of how it works from the New York Regional Reserve Bank of the US Federal Reserve system. Scroll down to the "Reserve Requirements and Money Creation" section. Here is what it says:
    "Reserve requirements affect the potential of the banking system to create transaction deposits. If the reserve requirement is 10%, for example, a bank that receives a $100 deposit may lend out $90 of that deposit. If the borrower then writes a check to someone who deposits the $90, the bank receiving that deposit can lend out $81. As the process continues, the banking system can expand the initial deposit of $100 into a maximum of $1,000 of money ($100+$90+81+$72.90+...=$1,000). In contrast, with a 20% reserve requirement, the banking system would be able to expand the initial $100 deposit into a maximum of $500 ($100+$80+$64+$51.20+...=$500). Thus, higher reserve requirements should result in reduced money creation and, in turn, in reduced economic activity."
    The link to this page is: http://www.newyorkfed.org/aboutthefed/fedpoint/fed45.html
  8. ^ The multiplier theory, by Hugo Hegeland, 1954, p. 1
  9. ^ http://www.mhhe.com/economics/mcconnell15e/graphics/mcconnell15eco/common/dothemath/moneymultiplier.html
  10. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2001), Principles of Macroeconomics
  11. ^ see Richard A. Werner (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan
  12. ^ The Great Yen Illusion, Oxford Applied Economics Discussion Papers No. 129, Institute of Economics and Statistics, University of Oxford, October 1991
  13. ^ Richard A. Werner (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan
  14. ^ Richard A. Werner (2005), New Paradigm in Macroeconomics, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan