Jump to content

Full-reserve banking: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Line 10: Line 10:
Proposals for full-reserve banking are rarely discussed in [[mainstream economics|mainstream]] circles, although it has been supported by economists such as Milton Friedman and Laurence Kotlikoff.<ref>Solow, Robert. 1992. "On the lender of last resort." In ''Financial Crises, Contagion, and the lender of last resort: a reader'', ed. Charles Goodhart and Gerhard Illing, p.203. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. [http://books.google.com/books?id=2486Jp8TjEcC&pg=PA201&dq=financial+crises,+contagion,+and+the+lender+of+last+resort&source=gbs_toc_r&cad=9#v=onepage&q=&f=false]</ref><ref>[http://people.bu.edu/kotlikoff/newweb/Abankingsystemwecantrust_4_2009.pdf], Laurence Kotlikoff</ref> By contrast, within the [[Austrian school]] of economics, the relative merits of full-reserve and fractional-reserve banking are the subject of active debate.<ref>[http://www.mises.org/Books/mysteryofbanking.pdf ''The Mystery of Banking''], Murray Rothbard</ref><ref name="urlHas fractional-reserve banking really passed the market test? (Controversy). | Independent Review (January, 2003)">{{cite web |url=http://www.accessmylibrary.com/coms2/summary_0286-2737288_ITM |title=Has fractional-reserve banking really passed the market test? (Controversy). | Independent Review (January, 2003) |format= |work= |accessdate=}}</ref><ref>[http://mises.org/story/3237 100% Reserves Now], Lucas M. Engelhardt</ref>
Proposals for full-reserve banking are rarely discussed in [[mainstream economics|mainstream]] circles, although it has been supported by economists such as Milton Friedman and Laurence Kotlikoff.<ref>Solow, Robert. 1992. "On the lender of last resort." In ''Financial Crises, Contagion, and the lender of last resort: a reader'', ed. Charles Goodhart and Gerhard Illing, p.203. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. [http://books.google.com/books?id=2486Jp8TjEcC&pg=PA201&dq=financial+crises,+contagion,+and+the+lender+of+last+resort&source=gbs_toc_r&cad=9#v=onepage&q=&f=false]</ref><ref>[http://people.bu.edu/kotlikoff/newweb/Abankingsystemwecantrust_4_2009.pdf], Laurence Kotlikoff</ref> By contrast, within the [[Austrian school]] of economics, the relative merits of full-reserve and fractional-reserve banking are the subject of active debate.<ref>[http://www.mises.org/Books/mysteryofbanking.pdf ''The Mystery of Banking''], Murray Rothbard</ref><ref name="urlHas fractional-reserve banking really passed the market test? (Controversy). | Independent Review (January, 2003)">{{cite web |url=http://www.accessmylibrary.com/coms2/summary_0286-2737288_ITM |title=Has fractional-reserve banking really passed the market test? (Controversy). | Independent Review (January, 2003) |format= |work= |accessdate=}}</ref><ref>[http://mises.org/story/3237 100% Reserves Now], Lucas M. Engelhardt</ref>


Some argue that the strict enforcement of full-reserve banking would mean that there would be no entity to carry out true "[[banking]]" functions, because full-reserve banking would restrict potential [[intermediation]] activities between lenders with short-term deposits and borrowers with longer-term borrowing needs. However, 100% reserve banking would still allow for long term lending and borrowing between parties with similar time horizons.<ref>[http://mises.org/story/1829 The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar], Murray Rothbard</ref><ref name=FBFB>[http://mises.org/journals/rae/pdf/RAE9_1_1.pdf Free Banking and the Free Bankers], Jörg Guido Hülsmann, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics (Vol. 9, No. 1)</ref>
Some argue that the strict enforcement of full-reserve banking would mean that there would be no entity to carry out true "[[banking]]" functions, because full-reserve banking would restrict potential [[intermediation]] activities between lenders with short-term deposits and borrowers with longer-term borrowing needs. This is incorrect, as the [[Diamond-Dybvig model]] of banking as liquidity insurance is not inherently about fractional reserve banking, but rather applies to any investment pool. According to this model, banks intermediate by allowing investors to participate in long term investment projects while still allowing some of them to withdraw their money in case they need it quicker than they expected. They accomplish this by pooling the money of a large number of investors and accurately predicting the proportion of investors who will need to withdraw quickly, in much the same manner that life insurance companies operate.<ref>Eric Maskin, The Browser[http://thebrowser.com/books/interviews/economic-theory-and-financial-crisis-eric-maskin]</ref> Diamond and Dybvig argue that banks provide insurance in this manner, and this can be accomplished by mutual funds as well as fractional reserve banks. Of course, 100% reserve banking would also allow for long term lending and borrowing between parties with similar time horizons.<ref>[http://mises.org/story/1829 The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar], Murray Rothbard</ref><ref name=FBFB>[http://mises.org/journals/rae/pdf/RAE9_1_1.pdf Free Banking and the Free Bankers], Jörg Guido Hülsmann, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics (Vol. 9, No. 1)</ref>


==The case for full reserve ==
==The case for full reserve ==

Revision as of 01:58, 26 October 2009

Full-reserve banking is a banking practice in which the full amount of each depositor's funds are available in reserve (as cash or other highly liquid assets) when each depositor had the legal right to withdraw them. Full-reserve banking was practiced historically by the Bank of Amsterdam and some other early banks but was displaced by fractional reserve banking after 1800.[1] Proposals for the restoration of full-reserve banking have been made, but are generally ignored or dismissed by mainstream economists, who believe that the costs of such a change would outweigh any benefits.

History

Debate over full reserve

Proposals for full-reserve banking are rarely discussed in mainstream circles, although it has been supported by economists such as Milton Friedman and Laurence Kotlikoff.[2][3] By contrast, within the Austrian school of economics, the relative merits of full-reserve and fractional-reserve banking are the subject of active debate.[4][5][6]

Some argue that the strict enforcement of full-reserve banking would mean that there would be no entity to carry out true "banking" functions, because full-reserve banking would restrict potential intermediation activities between lenders with short-term deposits and borrowers with longer-term borrowing needs. This is incorrect, as the Diamond-Dybvig model of banking as liquidity insurance is not inherently about fractional reserve banking, but rather applies to any investment pool. According to this model, banks intermediate by allowing investors to participate in long term investment projects while still allowing some of them to withdraw their money in case they need it quicker than they expected. They accomplish this by pooling the money of a large number of investors and accurately predicting the proportion of investors who will need to withdraw quickly, in much the same manner that life insurance companies operate.[7] Diamond and Dybvig argue that banks provide insurance in this manner, and this can be accomplished by mutual funds as well as fractional reserve banks. Of course, 100% reserve banking would also allow for long term lending and borrowing between parties with similar time horizons.[8][9]

The case for full reserve

This would eliminate (or at least greatly reduce) the financial risks associated with bank runs, as the bank would have all the money in reserve needed to pay depositors - regardless whether depositors actually claimed their money.[10][11][9]

This form of banking would also eliminate the need for a lender of last resort (such as a central bank), which is normally needed to support the banking system in times of systemic risk or financial contagion, as these financial risks would not exist in a full-reserve banking environment.[12] This simply requires that the resources available to the banks issuing credit money and demand deposits would be sufficient to convert all currency at once if so required. It was a central component in Social Credit proposals.[13]

In a full-reserve system all money is created by the federal government, and as a result all seigniorage revenue would also accrue to the federal government.[14] This is in contrast to the current system, where a large proportion of the money supply is in the form of demand deposits created by private banks.[15] When the Federal Reserve creates money and uses it to buy treasury bills, it collects seigniorage revenue in the form of interest payments which it then returns to the United States[16] (for example, in 2002 the United States earned $24.495 billion in this manner).[17] When a private bank creates money, the government cannot collect any seigniorage from it. Since the Federal Reserve has a target for the size of the money stock, any money created by private banks is money that is not created by the Fed and thus constitutes lost seigniorage.[18] Some consider this an illegitimate "privatization" of what should be a public good, with these profits being retained by the government to finance essential social services and capial works.[19][20][21]

Because fractional-reserve banking necessarily increases in the money supply and causes monetary inflation, some economists (most notably the Austrian School) consider this aspect of fractional-reserve banking to have deleterious and destabilizing effects on the economy over time.[22][23][9][24]

It is argued by these economists that, in contrast to fractional-reserve banking, full-reserve banking guarantees a stable money supply, which ensures that the means of exchange is not debased over time. This improves the efficiency of the price mechanism, promotes saving and the deferral of consumption, provides much greater confidence in the financial system and in the integrity of all commercial transactions and therefore encourages sustainable, non-speculative, productive investment.[25][26][9][27]

Reserve ratio

The reserve ratio of all banks operating in such a system would be 100%, making the deposit multiplier equal to one (1xM=M). The opposite of this system is fractional-reserve banking, in which the bank would hold only a fraction of all client deposits as reserves with the remainder used to supply loans and create credit.

Some advocates believe that full-reserve banking should only apply to demand not fixed loan deposits.[28] The distinction that full reservists make is that demand deposits such as checking and some modern savings accounts are available for immediate use by the owner of the account, whereas a traditional savings account is restricted.

Criticism

Among criticisms of a full-reserve banking system is the argument that full-reserve banking implicitly means that there is no government-controlled "monetary policy" at all. Critics might also argue that a full-reserve system leaves us with an inelastic currency. Proponents would likely argue that the lack of a government-manipulated currency (the lack of a "monetary policy") and the presence of a sound currency (as opposed to an "elastic" one) are advantages to a full-reserve system. More subtly, since full-reserve banking means that during periods of high demand for money, the prices of other goods must fall, the broader real economy may bear adjustment costs that are (in principle) no different from those it would bear during periods of moderate inflation (that is, if the cost of adjusting to absolute prices is low or negligible, moderate inflation should be no more problematic than moderate deflation).[29]

Pascal Salin, former professor at the Université Paris-Dauphine and former Mont Pelerin Society president, opposes such regulation of banking and disputes Murray Rothbard's characterization of fractional-reserve banking as a simple form of recursive embezzlement. He argues that a situation of perfect certainty doesn't exist even in a full-reserve banking system. He also argues that in a perfectly free banking system any customer must be free to choose the kind of notes and the system of payments for services he prefers since optimality cannot be defined independent of the wants of the individual.[30]

Advocates of full-reserve banking do not necessarily advocate that the government lay down regulations stipulating a full-reserve system. In fact, some economists, such as Murray Rothbard (of the Austrian School) believe that government intervention sustains fractional-reserve banking, as governments have formalized the practice by making it legal and supporting it through the creation of central banks. Murray Rothbard argues that in doing this they have prevented periodic bank runs and other natural checks that would otherwise be placed on banks by astute customers, anti-fractional-reserve consumer groups, and other such organizations. Rothbard expresses this concern, and argues the case for 100% gold or silver-backed money, in his book What Has Government Done to Our Money? and other prominent published works.[31]

Current examples

There are currently no examples of full reserve banking with an established history of operation. However, a variety of organisations aspire to provide full-reserve banking or claim to do so.

Islamic banking

In theory, Islamic banking is often synonymous with full-reserve banking, with banks achieving a 100% reserve ratio.[32][33] In practice, however, this is not the case, and no examples of 100 per cent reserve banking are observed. According to Islami Bank Bangladesh: [34]

The fractional reserve system versus 100% reserves would have different policy implications. Under the former system, banks would have the ability to draw profits on funds that they have exerted no productive effort. Such earning is against the original spirit of Islamic banking. One solution may lie in the nationalization of commercial banks, which has already occurred in most of these countries. As regards the latter, we have a fair amount of theoretical insight from the western literature but do not have any valuable empirical observations on the operations of 100% reserves even in countries that have adopted Islamic banking. These Islamic banks are still operating under fractional reserve system. Hence, the operation of monetary policy under 100% reserves system needs further research.

Digital gold

Since 1996, a form of private currency called digital gold currency has been in circulation. Many of these currency providers claim to act like full-reserve "private banks" with a one-to-one ratio of the currency they issue and the hard asset, usually gold or silver, that they store as reserves. The most prominent examples are GoldMoney, e-gold, and e-Bullion. The status of these latter two institutions is problematic.[35][36] Also available are physical gold exchangers and storage providers, such as BullionVault.

Some monetary reformers believe a new free market will emerge in money production and distribution, as the internet allows renewed decentralisation and competition in this area, eroding the central government's and bankers' old monopoly control of the means of exchange.[37][38] Some monetary reformers believe that in a genuine free market, where government did not impose a monopoly currency on the populace, a predominantly full-reserve banking system, backed by a gold standard or silver standard monetary system, would arise spontaneously out of the free market.[39]

Free Lakota Bank

The Free Lakota Bank claims to be a modern commodity-backed non-fractional reserve bank that issues, accepts for deposit, and circulates silver and gold. However, the precise status and legal existence of the bank is unclear.[40] A whois query of the website shows that the domain name is registered to "Rob Gray" at a residential address in Frisco, TX.[41] Commentary left by "David Foss" on articles featuring "Rob Gray" claim that Rob owes David money for artistic work. [42][43] The bank has no official affiliation with the proposed Republic of Lakotah and may not be a genuine financial institution. In response to inquiries, Russell Means, the spokesperson for the Lakotah nation has stated that the Republic of Lakotah is in no way associated with the "freelakotabank".[44]

See also

References

  1. ^ Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles, Jesus Huerta de Soto, First English edition (2006), pp. 98-114
  2. ^ Solow, Robert. 1992. "On the lender of last resort." In Financial Crises, Contagion, and the lender of last resort: a reader, ed. Charles Goodhart and Gerhard Illing, p.203. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. [1]
  3. ^ [2], Laurence Kotlikoff
  4. ^ The Mystery of Banking, Murray Rothbard
  5. ^ "Has fractional-reserve banking really passed the market test? (Controversy)". {{cite web}}: Text "Independent Review (January, 2003)" ignored (help)
  6. ^ 100% Reserves Now, Lucas M. Engelhardt
  7. ^ Eric Maskin, The Browser[3]
  8. ^ The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  9. ^ a b c d Free Banking and the Free Bankers, Jörg Guido Hülsmann, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics (Vol. 9, No. 1)
  10. ^ The Mystery of Banking, Murray Rothbard
  11. ^ The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  12. ^ Free Banking and Fractional Reserve Banking, Jörg Guido Hülsmann, Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics (Vol. 1, No. 3)
  13. ^ Social credit a distributist reform of the financial system by Oliver Heydorn
  14. ^ [4], Paul Krugman, Robin Wells, Macroeconomics 2nd Ed. Worth Publishers, Page 808
  15. ^ Krugman, pg 802
  16. ^ [5] GAO Report 04-283, Page 2
  17. ^ GAO Report, pg 14
  18. ^ [6] Paul Krugman, Robin Wells, Macroeconomics 2nd Ed. Worth Publishers, Page 816
  19. ^ Brown, Ellen H. (2007). Web of Debt. Baton Rouge, Louisiana: Third Millennium Press. ISBN 0979560802. Retrieved 2007-12-15.
  20. ^ Rowbotham, Michael (1998). The Grip of Death: A Study of Modern Money, Debt Slavery and Destructive Economics. Jon Carpenter Publishing. ISBN 9781897766408.
  21. ^ Stephen A. Zarlenga, The Lost Science of Money AMI (2002)
  22. ^ 100% Reserves Now, Lucas M. Engelhardt
  23. ^ The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  24. ^ The Mystery of Banking, Murray Rothbard
  25. ^ 100% Reserves Now, Lucas M. Engelhardt
  26. ^ The Case for a 100% Gold Dollar, Murray Rothbard
  27. ^ The Mystery of Banking, Murray Rothbard
  28. ^ Money Multiplier: Myth or Reality, Frank Shostak, 16 December 2002
  29. ^ Microfoundations and Macroeconomics: An Austrian Perspective, Steven Horwitz, pp. 223-232.
  30. ^ Free Banking and Fractional Reserves: A Comment, Pascal Salin
  31. ^ The Mystery of Banking, Murray Rothbard
  32. ^ A MONETARY SYSTEM WITH 100-PER CENT RESERVE REQUIREMENT AND THE GOLD STANDARD: THEORY, FACT AND POLICY
  33. ^ Siegfried, NA (2001). "Concepts of Paper Money in Islamic Legal Thought" ([dead link]Scholar search). Arab Law Quarterly. 16 (4): 319–332. doi:10.1163/A:1013840123393. ISSN 0268-0556. Retrieved 2006-10-16. {{cite journal}}: External link in |format= (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  34. ^ "Concept and ideology :: Issues and problems of Islamic banking".
  35. ^ Internet currency firm pleads guilty to money laundering
  36. ^ Murder of associate of e-Bullion
  37. ^ Not Losing Your Head, Speech by Lew Rockwell
  38. ^ Free Market Money System by F.A. Hayek
  39. ^ The Theory of Money and Credit, Ludwig von Mises
  40. ^ Lakota Freedom Delegation and Russell Means controversy
  41. ^ http://whois.domaintools.com/freelakotabank.com
  42. ^ "Interview with Mr. Rob Gray-American Open Currency Standard, AOCS". www.nowpublic.com. Retrieved 2009-10-15.
  43. ^ "Question Period: Rob Gray on gold and silver currency". westernstandard.blogs.com. Retrieved 2009-10-15.
  44. ^ Means, Russell. "?free lakota bank? : Russell Means Freedom". www.russellmeansfreedom.com. Retrieved 2009-08-09.