Jump to content

Asset-backed commercial paper program: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
m Typo/general fixing, replaced: loose → lose using AWB
cleanup
Line 1: Line 1:
'''Asset-backed commercial paper program''' ('''ABCP program''', '''ABCP Conduit''' or '''Conduit''') is set up as a program that issues short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]], [[commercial paper]]s called [[asset-backed commercial paper]]s, to finance medium- to long-term [[asset]]s.<ref name="swrt">Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl and Gustavo Suarez (2010). Securitization Without Risk Transfer, September 2010, NBER Working Paper No. 15730</ref> In terms of terminology, [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] usually refers to [[asset-backed commercial paper]], while [[financial conduit|ABCP conduit]] (or [[financial conduit|conduit]]) the program. The [[Maturity (finance)|maturities]] of [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] range up to 270 days but average about 30 days.<ref name="efc">Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang and Gustavo Suarez (2009). The evolution of a financial crisis: Panic in the asset-backed commercial paper market. Division of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board.</ref><ref name="frb">Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/cp/about.htm.</ref> Like [[bank]]s, ABCP programs provide [[liquidity]] and [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] transformation services.<ref name="efc"/> Because of this structure, ABCP conduits are considered to be part of the [[Shadow banking system]].<ref name="sb">Pozsar, Zoltan, Tobias Adrian, Adam Ashcraft and Hayley Boesky (2012). Shadow Banking. Staff Report No. 458. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports</ref> A common and prominent feature of many ABCP programs is that they were created by banks to fund bank [[asset]]s in an off-[[balance sheet]] way, possibly to avoid regulatory [[capital requirement]]s.<ref name="efc"/> Due to this character, ABCP is blamed to be one of the reasons of the [[Financial Crisis 2007-2009|2008-09 global financial crises]].
'''Asset-backed commercial paper program''' ('''ABCP program''', '''ABCP Conduit''' or '''Conduit''') is set up as a program that issues short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]], [[commercial paper]]s called [[asset-backed commercial paper]]s (ABCPs), to finance medium- to long-term [[asset]]s.<ref name="swrt">Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl and Gustavo Suarez (2010). Securitization Without Risk Transfer, September 2010, NBER Working Paper No. 15730</ref> In terms of terminology, ABCP usually refers to asset-backed commercial paper, while [[financial conduit|ABCP conduit]] (or conduit) the program. The [[Maturity (finance)|maturities]] of ABCP range up to 270 days but average about 30 days.<ref name="efc">Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang and Gustavo Suarez (2009). The evolution of a financial crisis: Panic in the asset-backed commercial paper market. Division of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board.</ref><ref name="frb">Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/cp/about.htm.</ref> Like [[bank]]s, ABCP programs provide [[liquidity]] and maturity transformation services.<ref name="efc"/> Because of this structure, ABCP conduits are considered to be part of the [[Shadow banking system]].<ref name="sb">Pozsar, Zoltan, Tobias Adrian, Adam Ashcraft and Hayley Boesky (2012). Shadow Banking. Staff Report No. 458. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports</ref> A common and prominent feature of many ABCP programs is that they were created by banks to fund bank assets in an off-[[balance sheet]] way, possibly to avoid regulatory [[capital requirement]]s.<ref name="efc"/> Due to this character, ABCP is blamed to be one of the reasons of the [[Financial Crisis 2007-2009|2008&ndash;09 global financial crises]].


==History==
==History==
ABCP programs first appeared in the mid-1980s. Initially, ABCP conduits were primarily sponsored by major [[commercial bank]]s as a means of providing [[trade receivable]] [[Finance|financing]] to their [[Corporation|corporate]] customers. Over the past decade, ABCP programs have grown to serve a wide variety of needs such as: asset-based [[Finance|financing]] for companies that cannot access the [[commercial paper]] market, warehousing assets prior to [[security]] issuance, investing in rated securities for arbitrage profit, providing leverage to [[mutual fund]]s, and off-[[balance sheet]] funding of bank [[asset]]s.<ref name="imf">The Fundamentals of Asset-Backed Commercial Paper. Structured Finance Special Report. http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2010/mcm/pdf/rutan1.pdf</ref>
ABCP programs first appeared in the mid-1980s. Initially, ABCP conduits were primarily sponsored by major [[commercial bank]]s as a means of providing [[trade receivable]] [[Finance|financing]] to their [[Corporation|corporate]] customers. Over the past decade, ABCP programs have grown to serve a wide variety of needs such as: asset-based financing for companies that cannot access the [[commercial paper]] market, warehousing assets prior to [[security]] issuance, investing in rated securities for arbitrage profit, providing leverage to [[mutual fund]]s, and off-[[balance sheet]] funding of bank [[asset]]s.<ref name="imf">The Fundamentals of Asset-Backed Commercial Paper. Structured Finance Special Report. http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2010/mcm/pdf/rutan1.pdf</ref>


Above all these service types, ABCP programs are commonly used by [[bank]]s to free up their [[capital requirement|regulatory capitals]] by moving the seemingly safe [[asset]]s off their [[balance sheet]]. Traditionally, [[bank]]s keep everything on their [[balance sheet]] and owners of the [[bank]] have to hold a certain amount of [[equity (finance)|equity]] to meet the [[capital requirement]]. This means if a [[bank]] wants to [[investment|invest]] in a large new project, i.e. increase its asset largely, it has to increase owners' equity proportionality. Moving such project off [[bank]]'s [[balance sheet]] eliminates the need of increasing equity. Through setting up ABCP conduits, [[bank]]s can fund [[asset]]s all by short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]].
Above all these service types, ABCP programs are commonly used by banks to free up their [[capital requirement|regulatory capitals]] by moving the seemingly safe assets off their balance sheet. Traditionally, banks keep everything on their balance sheet and owners of the bank have to hold a certain amount of [[equity (finance)|equity]] to meet the [[capital requirement]]. This means if a bank wants to [[investment|invest]] in a large new project, i.e. increase its asset largely, it has to increase owners' equity proportionality. Moving such project off bank's balance sheet eliminates the need of increasing equity. Through setting up ABCP conduits, banks can fund assets all by short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]].


In general, any asset class that has been funded in the term market has been funded in a conduit, and there are a wide variety of assets that are unique to the conduit market, however, at the time of 2007, the major asset of most ABCP programs is [[asset-backed security]] backed by residential [[mortgage]]s.<ref name="imf"/>
In general, any asset class that has been funded in the term market has been funded in a conduit, and there are a wide variety of assets that are unique to the conduit market, however, at the time of 2007, the major asset of most ABCP programs is [[asset-backed security]] backed by residential [[mortgage]]s.<ref name="imf"/>


As of September 2001, there were approximately 280 active ABCP programs, with more than $650 billion in outstanding.<ref name="fr">Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Explained. Fitch Ratings. http://people.stern.nyu.edu/igiddy/ABS/fitchabcp.pdf</ref> During the mid-2000s, [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] saw a steady rise in popularity because of their high ratings from the perspective of [[investor]]s and the low borrowing rates from companies who need money. Gradually, even more conservative [[investor]]s, such as [[Money market fund|money market mutual funds]] and retirement funds began purchasing [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]]. This optimism pushed the outstanding of [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] to $1.3 trillion by the time of July 2007.<ref name="swrt"/> At that time, [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] was the largest [[money market]] instrument in the United States, following by [[United States Treasury security|Treasury Bills]] with about $940 billion outstanding.<ref name="swrt"/> However, this trend came to an abrupt end in August 2007.<ref name="swrt"/>
As of September 2001, there were approximately 280 active ABCP programs, with more than $650 billion in outstanding.<ref name="fr">Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Explained. Fitch Ratings. http://people.stern.nyu.edu/igiddy/ABS/fitchabcp.pdf</ref> During the mid-2000s, ABCP saw a steady rise in popularity because of their high ratings from the perspective of investors and the low borrowing rates from companies who need money. Gradually, even more conservative investors, such as [[Money market fund|money market mutual funds]] and retirement funds began purchasing ABCP. This optimism pushed the outstanding of ABCP to $1.3 trillion by the time of July 2007.<ref name="swrt"/> At that time, ABCP was the largest [[money market]] instrument in the United States, following by [[United States Treasury security|Treasury Bills]] with about $940 billion outstanding.<ref name="swrt"/> However, this trend came to an abrupt end in August 2007.<ref name="swrt"/>


During 2007, as negative information about U.S. residential [[mortgage]]s spreads out, securities backed with [[mortgage]]s, including [[sub-prime mortgage]]s, widely held by ABCP programs of financial firms globally, started to lose their value. [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] investors started to worry about the value of the asset backing their [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] and stopped rolling over their position. At the beginning, sponsor banks have enough liquid to pay off these liabilities, but when optimism turns into pessimism, things get ugly.<ref name="swrt"/> See [[Subprime mortgage crisis]] for further details.
During 2007, as negative information about U.S. residential mortgages spreads out, securities backed with mortgages, including [[sub-prime mortgage]]s, widely held by ABCP programs of financial firms globally, started to lose their value. ABCP investors started to worry about the value of the asset backing their ABCP and stopped rolling over their position. At the beginning, sponsor banks have enough liquid to pay off these liabilities, but lack of market confidence can create a [[subprime mortgage crisis]].
On August 2007, the French bank [[BNP Paribas]] halted withdrawals from three funds invested in [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] and suspended calculation of [[net asset value]]s. Even though [[Default (finance)|defaults]] on mortgages had been rising throughout 2007, the suspension of withdrawals by [[BNP Paribas]] has a profound effect on [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market. The interest rate spread of over-night [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] and [[Federal funds rate]] increased from 10 [[basis point]]s to 150 [[basis point]]s within one day of announcement.
On August 2007, the French bank [[BNP Paribas]] halted withdrawals from three funds invested in ABCP and suspended calculation of [[net asset value]]s. Even though [[Default (finance)|defaults]] on mortgages had been rising throughout 2007, the suspension of withdrawals by BNP Paribas has a profound effect on ABCP market. The interest rate spread of over-night ABCP and [[Federal funds rate]] increased from 10 [[basis point]]s to 150 basis points within one day of announcement.


Subsequently, the [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market experienced a modern-day [[bank run]]. Several ABCP conduits fall victims to liquidity crisis, and so are their sponsor [[financial institution]]s.<ref name="swrt"/> Since banks only need to keep regulatory capital for on-[[balance sheet]] assets, and none for the assets funded by ABCP conduits, they get into huge trouble paying back investors who refuse to roll over their [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]]. Several major [[financial institution]]s collapsed in the following year because of solvency issues and have to be bailed out by government.<ref name="swrt"/> See [[Financial crisis of 2007–2008]] for details on the crisis and see [[Great Recession]] for the recession triggered by the financial crisis.
Subsequently, the ABCP market experienced a modern-day [[bank run]]. Several ABCP conduits fall victims to liquidity crisis, and so are their sponsor [[financial institution]]s.<ref name="swrt"/> Since banks only need to keep regulatory capital for on-balance sheet assets, and none for the assets funded by ABCP conduits, they get into huge trouble paying back investors who refuse to roll over their ABCP. Several major financial institutions collapsed in the following year because of solvency issues and have to be bailed out by government.<ref name="swrt"/> See [[Financial crisis of 2007–2008]] for details on the crisis and see [[Great Recession]] for the recession triggered by the financial crisis.


In December 2007, [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] outstanding dropped from $1.3 trillion to $833 billion.<ref name="swrt"/> By the end of 2008, there is no [[Structured investment vehicle|SIV]] left. As of March 2013, the outstanding of [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] is about $300 billion.<ref name="outstanding">Asset-backed Commercial Paper Outstanding. Federal Reserve Economic Data. http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/ABCOMP</ref>
In December 2007, ABCP outstanding dropped from $1.3 trillion to $833 billion.<ref name="swrt"/> By the end of 2008, there is no [[Structured investment vehicle|SIV]] left. As of March 2013, the outstanding of ABCP is about $300 billion.<ref name="outstanding">Asset-backed Commercial Paper Outstanding. Federal Reserve Economic Data. http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/ABCOMP</ref>


==Structure==
==Structure==
An ABCP conduit is set up by a sponsoring [[financial institution]] (henceforth, sponsor). The sole purpose of a conduit is to purchase and hold [[financial asset]]s from a variety of [[asset]] sellers.<ref name="swrt"/> The conduit finances the [[asset]]s by selling [[asset-backed commercial paper]] to outside [[investor]]s such as [[money market fund]]s or other “safe asset” [[investor]]s like retirement funds.<ref name="swrt"/>
An ABCP conduit is set up by a sponsoring [[financial institution]] (henceforth, sponsor). The sole purpose of a conduit is to purchase and hold [[financial asset]]s from a variety of asset sellers.<ref name="swrt"/> The conduit finances the assets by selling asset-backed commercial paper] to outside investors such as [[money market fund]]s or other "safe asset" investors like retirement funds.<ref name="swrt"/>


Take the conduit Grampian as an example. Grampian is a conduit set up and managed by [[HBOS]]. [[HBOS]]’s management responsibilities consist of selecting the assets (Airbus, [[mortgage]]s, etc.) to be purchased by Grampian and issuing short-term [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] in order to [[finance]] the [[asset]]s (Airbus, [[mortgage]]s, etc.). [[HBOS]] sells the [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] to outside [[investor]]s such as Fidelity and rolls over the [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] at regular intervals.<ref name="swrt"/>
Take the conduit Grampian as an example. Grampian is a conduit set up and managed by [[HBOS]]. HBOS's management responsibilities consist of selecting the assets (Airbus, mortgages, etc.) to be purchased by Grampian and issuing short-term ABCP in order to finance the assets (Airbus, mortgages, etc.). HBOS sells the ABCP to outside investors such as Fidelity and rolls over the ABCP at regular intervals.<ref name="swrt"/>


[[File:Structure of ABCP conduit.jpg|thumbnail|right|Structure of a ABCP conduit]]
Figure 1 illustrates the typical conduit structure.


As in banks, the [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of assets in ABCP conduits generally is longer than the maturity of the [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]]. More than half of ABCP daily issuance has maturities of 1 to 4 days, referred to as "overnight", and the average maturity of outstanding paper is about 30 days.<ref name="efc"/> ABCP programs regularly roll over their liabilities and use proceeds from new issuances to pay off maturing [[commercial paper]]. [[Loan]] and lease receivables, which are assets commonly purchased by ABCP conduits, likely have terms of 30 days or more, and while relatively short, are still longer than most ABCP.<ref name="swrt"/> Most of the conduit assets are medium- to long-term assets with maturities of three to five yours.<ref name="swrt"/>
[[File:Structure of ABCP conduit.jpg|thumbnail|right|Figure 1. Structure of a ABCP conduit]]

As in banks, the [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of assets in ABCP conduits generally is longer than the [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of the [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]]. More than half of ABCP daily issuance has [[Maturity (finance)|maturities]] of 1 to 4 days, referred to as “overnight”, and the average [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of outstanding paper is about 30 days.<ref name="efc"/> ABCP programs regularly roll over their liabilities and use proceeds from new issuances to pay off maturing [[commercial paper]]. [[Loan]] and lease receivables, which are assets commonly purchased by ABCP conduits, likely have terms of 30 days or more, and while relatively short, are still longer than most [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]].<ref name="swrt"/> Most of the conduit assets are medium- to long-term assets with maturities of three to five yours.<ref name="swrt"/>


===Financial institution (sponsor)===
===Financial institution (sponsor)===
The sponsors of the conduit play two roles: manage [[asset]]s and provide [[liquidity]]. Sponsor types range from large U.S. [[commercial bank]]s to non-bank institutions, like mortgage lenders and asset managers. Large U.S. [[bank]]s have long sponsored ABCP programs, some smaller U.S. [[bank]]s sponsor a very modest share. Foreign [[bank]]s sponsor a substantial share of [[asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]], about 40 percent in 2007. Non-bank institutions, such as [[mortgage]] lenders, finance companies, or [[Asset management|asset managers]], also sponsor a considerable share of the market. Programs sponsored by non-bank institutions grew more dramatically than other programs from 2004 to 2007, more than doubling in assets to $400 billion.<ref name="efc"/>
The sponsors of the conduit play two roles: manage [[asset]]s and provide [[liquidity]]. Sponsor types range from large U.S. [[commercial bank]]s to non-bank institutions, like mortgage lenders and asset managers. Large U.S. banks have long sponsored ABCP programs, some smaller U.S. banks sponsor a very modest share. Foreign banks sponsor a substantial share of ABCP, about 40 percent in 2007. Non-bank institutions, such as mortgage lenders, finance companies, or [[Asset management|asset managers]], also sponsor a considerable share of the market. Programs sponsored by non-bank institutions grew more dramatically than other programs from 2004 to 2007, more than doubling in assets to $400 billion.<ref name="efc"/>
::The ten largest sponsors as of January 2007 are:<ref name="swrt"/>
The ten largest sponsors as of January 2007 are:<ref name="swrt"/>
::#[[Citigroup]] (U.S.)
#[[Citigroup]] (U.S.)
::#[[ABN AMRO]] (Netherlands)
#[[ABN AMRO]] (Netherlands)
::#[[Bank of America]] (U.S.)
#[[Bank of America]] (U.S.)
::#[[HBOS]] Pls (U.K.)
#[[HBOS]] Pls (U.K.)
::#[[JPMorgan Chase|JP Morgan]] (U.S.)
#[[JPMorgan Chase|JP Morgan]] (U.S.)
::#[[HSBC]] (U.K.)
#[[HSBC]] (U.K.)
::#[[Deutsche Bank|Deutsche Bank AG]] (Germany)
#[[Deutsche Bank|Deutsche Bank AG]] (Germany)
::#[[Société Générale]] (France)
#[[Société Générale]] (France)
::#[[Barclays]] Plc (U.K.)
#[[Barclays]] Plc (U.K.)
::#[[Rabobank]] (Netherlands)
#[[Rabobank]] (Netherlands)


Conduits can generate significant risks for the sponsor. The sponsor’s guarantee typically covers the conduit’s roll-over risk, which is the risk that a conduit cannot refinance maturing commercial paper, possibly because of a deterioration of conduit asset values. In that case, the sponsor has to assume the losses from lower asset values, because under the guarantee sponsors are required to repurchase assets [[Par value|at par]]. In exchange for assuming this risk, the sponsor receives the conduit profits.<ref name="swrt"/>
Conduits can generate significant risks for the sponsor. The sponsor’s guarantee typically covers the conduit’s roll-over risk, which is the risk that a conduit cannot refinance maturing commercial paper, possibly because of a deterioration of conduit asset values. In that case, the sponsor has to assume the losses from lower asset values, because under the guarantee sponsors are required to repurchase assets [[Par value|at par]]. In exchange for assuming this risk, the sponsor receives the conduit profits.<ref name="swrt"/>


====Types of [[guarantee]]s====
====Types of guarantees====
Conduit sponsors use four different types of [[guarantee]]s which provide different levels of [[insurance]] to outside [[investor]]s. The four types of [[guarantee]]s, ranked from strongest to weakest, are full credit [[guarantee]]s (“full credit”), full liquidity [[guarantee]]s (“full liquidity”), extendible notes [[guarantee]]s (“extendible notes”), and [[guarantee]]s arranged via [[structured investment vehicle]]s (“[[structured investment vehicle|SIV]]”).<ref name="swrt"/>
Conduit sponsors use four different types of guarantees which provide different levels of insurance to outside investors. The four types of guarantees, ranked from strongest to weakest, are full credit guarantees ("full credit"), full liquidity guarantees ("full liquidity"), extendible notes guarantees ("extendible notes"), and guarantees arranged via [[structured investment vehicle]]s (SIV).<ref name="swrt"/>


=====Full credit=====
=====Full credit=====
Full credit [[guarantee]]s are [[guarantee]]s that require the sponsor to pay off maturing [[asset-backed commercial paper]] independent of the conduit’s [[asset]] values. From a regulatory perspective, full credit [[guarantee]]s are considered equivalent to on-[[balance sheet]] financing, because they expose banks to the same risks as [[asset]]s on the balance sheet. Therefore, if the bank offer full credit [[guarantee]], the backing assets will be on the [[balance sheet]], thus are included in the calculation of [[Financial capital|capital]] needed to meat [[capital requirement]]. In practice, these [[guarantee]]s are infrequently used by [[financial institution]]s that have to satisfy bank [[capital requirement]]s.<ref name="swrt"/>
Full credit guarantees are guarantees that require the sponsor to pay off maturing asset-backed commercial paper independent of the conduit's asset values. From a regulatory perspective, full credit guarantees are considered equivalent to on-[[balance sheet]] financing, because they expose banks to the same risks as assets on the balance sheet. Therefore, if the bank offer full credit guarantee, the backing assets will be on the balance sheet, thus are included in the calculation of [[Financial capital|capital]] needed to meat [[capital requirement]]. In practice, these guarantees are infrequently used by financial institutions that have to satisfy bank capital requirements.<ref name="swrt"/>


=====Full liquidity=====
=====Full liquidity=====
Full liquidity [[guarantee]]s are similar to full credit [[guarantee]]s with the main difference being that the sponsor only needs to pay off maturing [[asset-backed commercial paper]] if the conduit [[asset]]s are not in [[default (finance)|default]]. Hence, there is a possibility that full liquidity [[guarantee]]s expire before the [[asset-backed commercial paper]] matures. This form of [[guarantee]]s is weaker than full credit, but from the bank’s side, they can move these assets off the [[balance sheet]].<ref name="swrt"/>
Full liquidity guarantees are similar to full credit guarantees with the main difference being that the sponsor only needs to pay off maturing asset-backed commercial paper if the conduit assets are not in [[default (finance)|default]]. Hence, there is a possibility that full liquidity guarantees expire before the asset-backed commercial paper matures. This form of guarantees is weaker than full credit, but from the bank's side, they can move these assets off the balance sheet.<ref name="swrt"/>


=====Extendible notes=====
=====Extendible notes=====
Extendible notes [[guarantee]]s are similar to full liquidity [[guarantee]]s with the main difference being that the conduit issuer has the discretion to extend maturing [[commercial paper]] for a limited period of time (usually 60 days or less). By extending the [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of the [[commercial paper]], it is more likely that the conduit’s [[asset]]s are in [[default (finance)|default]] before the [[commercial paper]] matures. From the viewpoint of an outside [[investor]], extendible notes [[guarantee]]s are therefore riskier than full liquidity [[guarantee]]s. This [[guarantee]] was used by weaker [[financial institution]]s and by conduits with higher quality [[asset]]s.<ref name="swrt"/>
Extendible notes guarantees are similar to full liquidity guarantees with the main difference being that the conduit issuer has the discretion to extend maturing commercial paper for a limited period of time (usually 60 days or less). By extending the [[Maturity (finance)|maturity]] of the commercial paper, it is more likely that the conduit's assets are in default before the commercial paper matures. From the viewpoint of an outside investor, extendible notes guarantees are therefore riskier than full liquidity guarantees. This guarantee was used by weaker financial institutions and by conduits with higher quality assets.<ref name="swrt"/>


=====[[structured investment vehicle|SIV]]=====
=====SIV=====
[[structured investment vehicle|SIV]] [[guarantee]]s are also similar to full liquidity [[guarantee]]s with the main difference being that [[structured investment vehicle|SIV]] [[guarantee]]s only cover a share of the conduit [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]] (usually around 25%). Since [[structured investment vehicle|SIV]] [[guarantee]]s do not cover all conduit [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]], they are considered partial insurance to outside [[investor]]s. [[structured investment vehicle|SIV]] [[guarantee]]s were primarily used by [[commercial bank]]s and other [[financial institution]]s to cover high quality [[asset]]s.<ref name="swrt"/>
[[structured investment vehicle|SIV]] guarantees are also similar to full liquidity guarantees with the main difference being that SIV guarantees only cover a share of the conduit [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]] (usually around 25%). Since SIV guarantees do not cover all conduit liabilities, they are considered partial insurance to outside investors. SIV guarantees were primarily used by commercial banks and other financial institutions to cover high quality assets.<ref name="swrt"/>


===[[Asset]] types===
===Asset types===
The [[asset]] types that conduits invested in are mostly [[Asset-backed security|asset-backed securities]] (ABS), [[Mortgage loan|residential mortgages]], [[Loan|commercial loans]] and [[Collateralized debt obligation|CDOs]]. Most of the [[asset]]s are [[Bond credit rating|AAA-rated]], some holds un-rated [[asset]]s generated by the sponsor [[financial institution]].<ref name="swrt"/> The [[asset]] origins are mostly Unites States (68%), Germany (15%) and United Kingdom (10%).<ref name="gb">Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl(2010). Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances&quest; Asset-Backed Commercial Paper during the Financial Crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58(1), 37-73.</ref>
The asset types that conduits invested in are mostly [[Asset-backed security|asset-backed securities]] (ABS), [[Mortgage loan|residential mortgages]], [[Loan|commercial loans]] and [[Collateralized debt obligation|CDOs]]. Most of the assets are [[Bond credit rating|AAA-rated]], some holds un-rated assets generated by the sponsor financial institution.<ref name="swrt"/> The asset origins are mostly United States (68%), Germany (15%) and United Kingdom (10%).<ref name="gb">Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl(2010). Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances&quest; Asset-Backed Commercial Paper during the Financial Crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58(1), 37-73.</ref>


===Outside [[investor]]s===
===Outside investors===
The outside [[investor]]s are mostly risk sensitive [[investor]]s like [[Money market fund]] and retirement funds.
The outside investors are mostly risk sensitive investors like [[money market fund]] and retirement funds.


==Economic Benefits of ABCP Programs==
==Benefits==
Originally, banks set up ABCP conduits to finance only safe [[asset]]s off-[[balance sheet]]. Since these [[asset]]s are considered safe, it is socially optimal for banks to invest more at a lower cost. ABCP conduit provides a way to free up [[Capital requirement|regulatory capital]], and thus achieve higher efficiency. At the same time, since safe [[asset]]s are moved out of [[balance sheet]], policy makers can target regulatory [[capital requirement]]s only on the risky [[asset]]s, which is what remains on the [[balance sheet]].
Originally, banks set up ABCP conduits to finance only safe assets off-balance sheet. Since these assets are considered safe, it is socially optimal for banks to invest more at a lower cost. ABCP conduit provides a way to free up regulatory capital, and thus achieve higher efficiency. At the same time, since safe assets are moved out of balance sheet, policy makers can target regulatory capital requirements only on the risky assets, which is what remains on the balance sheet.


==Economic Costs of ABCP Programs==
==Costs==


However, due to no [[capital requirement]] for off-[[balance sheet]] assets, ABCP conduits also induce excessive risk taking. For example, banks may spread their [[capital requirement|capital]] very thin, and invest in highly risky projects that they would not have invested absent the mitigating effects of ABCP conduit on regulatory [[capital requirement]]s. Especially when the sponsor bank is big, ABCP induces high [[moral hazard]]. When good state realized, the risky project will yield very high returns, but when bad state realized, the big bank expect government to [[bailout|bail it out]]. Therefore, banks optimally take on more risk because it does not care about the losses that occur in those states of nature when it goes [[Bankruptcy|bankrupt]]. [[Creditor]]s will be bailed out and the [[interest rate]] at which the [[bank]] can borrow is therefore insensitive to [[bankruptcy]] risk. This is called "risk shifting"—shifting the risk from [[bank]]s to the public. Most likely, policy makers find it optimal to [[bailout|bail out]] the [[bank]], but needless to say, it is socially very costly.
However, due to no capital requirement for off-balance sheet assets, ABCP conduits also induce excessive risk taking. For example, banks may spread their capital very thin, and invest in highly risky projects that they would not have invested absent the mitigating effects of ABCP conduit on regulatory capital requirements. Especially when the sponsor bank is big, ABCP induces high [[moral hazard]]. When good state realized, the risky project will yield very high returns, but when bad state realized, the big bank expect government to [[bailout|bail it out]]. Therefore, banks optimally take on more risk because it does not care about the losses that occur in those states of nature when it goes [[Bankruptcy|bankrupt]]. [[Creditor]]s will be bailed out and the [[interest rate]] at which the bank can borrow is therefore insensitive to bankruptcy risk. This is called "risk shifting"—shifting the risk from banks to the public. Most likely, policy makers find it optimal to bail out the bank, but needless to say, it is socially very costly.


==Risks==
==Risk of ABCP Programs==
Most conduits minimize their [[credit risk]] by holding a [[Diversification (finance)|diversified]] [[Portfolio (finance)|portfolio]] of high quality [[asset]]s. Typically, they are restricted to purchasing [[Bond credit rating|AAA-rated]] [[asset]]s or unrated [[asset]]s of similar quality. Some conduits exclusively purchase unrated [[asset]]s originated by their sponsoring [[financial institution]]s. Other conduits mostly purchase [[Securitization|securitized]] assets originated by other [[financial institution]]s. Many conduits combine the two strategies by purchasing both securitized and un-securitized [[asset]]s from several [[financial institution]]s.<ref name="swrt"/>
Most conduits minimize their [[credit risk]] by holding a [[Diversification (finance)|diversified]] [[Portfolio (finance)|portfolio]] of high quality assets. Typically, they are restricted to purchasing [[Bond credit rating|AAA-rated]] assets or unrated [[asset]]s of similar quality. Some conduits exclusively purchase unrated assets originated by their sponsoring financial institutions. Other conduits mostly purchase [[Securitization|securitized]] assets originated by other financial institutions. Many conduits combine the two strategies by purchasing both securitized and un-securitized assets from several financial institutions.<ref name="swrt"/>


Outside [[investor]]s consider [[asset-backed commercial paper]] a safe [[investment]] for three reasons. First, the pool of conduit [[asset]]s is used as [[Collateral (finance)|collateral]] to secure the [[asset-backed commercial paper]]. Second, the conduit’s sponsor provides [[guarantee]]s to the conduit, which ensures that the sponsor repays maturing [[asset-backed commercial paper]] in case the conduit is unable to pay off the maturing paper itself. Third, [[asset-backed commercial paper]] is very short-term, so that [[investor]]s can easily liquidate their investment by not rolling over maturing [[asset-backed commercial paper]].<ref name="swrt"/>
Outside investors consider asset-backed commercial paper a safe investment for three reasons. First, the pool of conduit assets is used as [[Collateral (finance)|collateral]] to secure the asset-backed commercial paper. Second, the conduit's sponsor provides guarantees to the conduit, which ensures that the sponsor repays maturing ABCPs in case the conduit is unable to pay off the maturing paper itself. Third, ABCP is very short-term, so that investors can easily liquidate their investment by not rolling over maturing ABCPs.<ref name="swrt"/>


However, [[asset]] holdings of ABCP conduits, like at banks, are not transparent. While the vast majority of ABCP programs have credit ratings from the major [[Credit rating agency|rating agencies]], credit support mechanisms vary and the specific [[asset]]s held in the programs are not widely known. For example, some ABCP programs viewed their holdings to be ‘proprietary’ investment strategies and deliberately did not disclose. Thus, random events or concerns about an economic downturn can create uncertainty about [[asset]] values. This uncertainty is greater when less information is available about the [[asset]]s.<ref name="efc"/>
However, asset holdings of ABCP conduits, like at banks, are not transparent. While the vast majority of ABCP programs have credit ratings from the major [[Credit rating agency|rating agencies]], credit support mechanisms vary and the specific assets held in the programs are not widely known. For example, some ABCP programs viewed their holdings to be 'proprietary' investment strategies and deliberately did not disclose. Thus, random events or concerns about an economic downturn can create uncertainty about asset values. This uncertainty is greater when less information is available about the assets.<ref name="efc"/>


While ABCP programs are like banks, a key distinction, with important implications for financial stability, is that ABCP programs do not have explicit [[deposit insurance]] provided by the government. Most traditional ABCP programs are sponsored by [[commercial bank]]s that provide explicit [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] support.<ref name="efc"/>
While ABCP programs are like banks, a key distinction, with important implications for financial stability, is that ABCP programs do not have explicit [[deposit insurance]] provided by the government. Most traditional ABCP programs are sponsored by commercial banks that provide explicit [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] support.<ref name="efc"/>


ABCP conduit induces regulatory arbitrage and excessive risk taking. With so few skin in the game, banks will increase their investments, and especially investments in risky projects with negative expected returns. The resulting high leverage and high risk will increase [[systemic risk]] of the [[financial system]], which further impose huge risk on the broader economy.
==Risks of ABCP Programs for the Broader Economy==
As mentioned in the benefits section, ABCP conduit induces regulatory arbitrage and excessive risk taking. With so few skin in the game, banks will increase their investments, and especially investments in risky projects with negative expected returns. The resulting high leverage and high risk will increase [[systemic risk]] of the [[financial system]], which further impose huge risk on the broader economy. See [[Systemic risk]] for details on [[systemic risk]].


==Types of ABCP programs==
==Types==
There are five principal types of ABCP program:<ref name="imf"/>
There are five principal types of ABCP program:<ref name="imf"/>
::*General purpose multi-seller
*General purpose multi-seller
::*Credit arbitrage
*Credit arbitrage
::*[[Structured investment vehicle]] (SIV)
*[[Structured investment vehicle]] (SIV)
::*Single-seller
*Single-seller
::*Loan-backed
*Loan-backed


===General purpose multi-seller===
===General purpose multi-seller===
The most traditional ABCP program is a multi-seller program, in which a conduit purchases [[receivables]] and [[loan]]s from multiple firms. The sponsor is typically a [[financial institution]] that provides the conduit with a committed [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] line, administers its daily operations, and sometimes also provides the conduit with credit enhancement through a letter of [[credit (finance)|credit]] that absorbs credit losses. At the end of July 2007, just before the widespread turmoil, there were 98 multi-seller programs in the U.S. [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market with outstanding of $525 billion, about 45 percent of total [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] outstanding.<ref name="efc"/>
The most traditional ABCP program is a multi-seller program, in which a conduit purchases [[receivables]] and [[loan]]s from multiple firms. The sponsor is typically a financial institution that provides the conduit with a committed [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] line, administers its daily operations, and sometimes also provides the conduit with credit enhancement through a letter of [[credit (finance)|credit]] that absorbs credit losses. At the end of July 2007, just before the widespread turmoil, there were 98 multi-seller programs in the U.S. ABCP market with outstanding of $525 billion, about 45 percent of total ABCP outstanding.<ref name="efc"/>


===Credit arbitrage===
===Credit arbitrage===
These programs involve [[bank]]s sponsoring conduits to finance long-term [[asset]]s through a special purpose entity that has a lower [[Capital requirement|regulatory capital charge]] than if the [[asset]]s were held on [[balance sheet]]. The sponsor banks typically provide full [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] support. By using off-[[balance sheet]] funding, commercial banks exploit regulatory capital arbitrage opportunities. In July 2007, there were 35 programs that accounted for about 13 percent of the U.S. [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market.<ref name="efc"/>
These programs involve banks sponsoring conduits to finance long-term assets through a special purpose entity that has a lower [[Capital requirement|regulatory capital charge]] than if the assets were held on balance sheet. The sponsor banks typically provide full liquidity support. By using off-balance sheet funding, commercial banks exploit regulatory capital arbitrage opportunities. In July 2007, there were 35 programs that accounted for about 13 percent of the U.S. ABCP market.<ref name="efc"/>


===SIV===
===SIV===
[[Structured investment vehicle]]s (or [[Structured investment vehicle|SIVs]]) fund highly rated [[Security (finance)|securities]]. But unlike the credit arbitrage programs, [[Structured investment vehicle|SIVs]] do not have explicit agreements with their sponsoring [[bank]]s for committed back-stop [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] lines covering all their short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]]. Instead [[Structured investment vehicle|SIVs]] relied on dynamic [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] management strategies, which involved liquidating [[asset]]s to pay investors if needed. At their peak in July 2007, there were 35 [[Structured investment vehicle|SIVs]] that accounted for $84 billion of U.S. [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]]. Some [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] is issued by [[collateralized debt obligation]]s ([[collateralized debt obligation|CDOs]]), sometimes called SIV-lites. [[collateralized debt obligation|CDOs]] are similar to [[Structured investment vehicle|SIVs]] in structure, but are not actively managed and tend to rely on explicit but only partial [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] support. There were 36 [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] [[collateralized debt obligation|CDO]] programs in July 2007, with [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] outstanding of $47 billion.<ref name="efc"/>
SIVs fund highly rated [[Security (finance)|securities]]. But unlike the credit arbitrage programs, SIVs do not have explicit agreements with their sponsoring banks for committed back-stop [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] lines covering all their short-term [[Liability (financial accounting)|liabilities]]. Instead SIVs relied on dynamic liquidity management strategies, which involved liquidating assets to pay investors if needed. At their peak in July 2007, there were 35 SIVs that accounted for $84 billion of U.S. ABCP. Some [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] is issued by [[collateralized debt obligation]]s (CDOs), sometimes called SIV-lites. CDOs are similar to SIVs in structure, but are not actively managed and tend to rely on explicit but only partial liquidity support. There were 36 ABCP CDO programs in July 2007, with ABCP outstanding of $47 billion.<ref name="efc"/>


===Single-seller===
===Single-seller===
Single-seller programs involve a conduit that issues [[commercial paper]] backed by [[asset]]s from only one originator, which frequently also sponsors the conduit. The majority of single-seller conduits mainly fund credit-card receivables, [[mortgage]]s, [[Mortgage-backed security|mortgage-backed securities]], or [[Loan|auto loans]]. Such programs tended not to have explicit [[Market liquidity|liquidity]] support, but were thought to be implicitly supported by originators. In July 2007, there were 40 non-mortgage single-seller programs, about 11 percent of the U.S. [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market. There also were 11 mortgage single-seller programs that primarily warehoused mortgages prior to their [[securitization]].<ref name="efc"/>
Single-seller programs involve a conduit that issues commercial paper backed by assets from only one originator, which frequently also sponsors the conduit. The majority of single-seller conduits mainly fund credit-card receivables, mortgages, [[Mortgage-backed security|mortgage-backed securities]], or [[Loan|auto loans]]. Such programs tended not to have explicit liquidity support, but were thought to be implicitly supported by originators. In July 2007, there were 40 non-mortgage single-seller programs, about 11 percent of the U.S. ABCP market. There also were 11 mortgage single-seller programs that primarily warehoused mortgages prior to their [[securitization]].<ref name="efc"/>


===[[Loan]]-backed===
===Loan-backed===
[[Loan]]-backed programs are [[bank]]-sponsored programs and fund direct [[loan]]s to the bank’s corporate customers. These [[loan]]s are generally closely managed by the [[bank]], and have a variety of covenants designed to reduce credit risk.<ref name="imf"/>
Loan-backed programs are bank-sponsored programs and fund direct loans to the bank's corporate customers. These loans are generally closely managed by the bank, and have a variety of covenants designed to reduce credit risk.<ref name="imf"/>


==Relation to 2008-09 global financial crises==
==Relation to 2008-09 global financial crises==
Economists think that the main feature of many [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] is that they were created by banks to fund bank [[asset]]s in an off-[[balance sheet]] way, possibly to avoid regulatory [[capital requirements]].<ref name="efc"/> Thus the [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] market may be inherently unstable and a source of [[systemic risk]].<ref name="efc"/>
Economists think that the main feature of many ABCP is that they were created by banks to fund bank [[asset]]s in an off-balance sheet way, possibly to avoid regulatory [[capital requirements]].<ref name="efc"/> Thus the ABCP market may be inherently unstable and a source of [[systemic risk]].<ref name="efc"/>

Before the [[Financial crisis of 2007–2008|2008-09 financial crises]], the global financial system "manufactured" risk-less [[asset]]s, totaling over $1.2 trillion, by selling short-term [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] to risk-averse [[investor]]s, predominantly U.S. [[money market fund]]s, and investing the proceeds primarily in long-term U.S. [[assets]].


Before the [[Financial crisis of 2007–2008|2008-09 financial crises]], the global financial system "manufactured" risk-less assets, totaling over $1.2 trillion, by selling short-term ABCP to risk-averse investors, predominantly U.S. [[money market fund]]s, and investing the proceeds primarily in long-term U.S. assets.
As negative information about U.S. [[asset]]s became apparent in August 2007, banks experienced difficulties in rolling over [[Asset-backed commercial paper|ABCP]] and as a result several banks have to be [[Bailout|bailed out]] by the government.<ref name="gb"/> Banks' solvency issues and [[asset]] deterioration seriously damaged [[investor]] confidence. Meanwhile, liquidity shortage tightened credits going to production sectors. As a result, economies worldwide slowed and international trade declined. Governments and [[central bank]]s responded with unprecedented [[fiscal stimulus]], [[monetary policy]] expansion and institutional [[bailout]]s.<ref name="sbn">Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, Elias Papaioannou and Fabrizio Perri(2012). Global banks and crisis transmission. Journal of International Economics.</ref>


As negative information about U.S. assets became apparent in August 2007, banks experienced difficulties in rolling over ABCP and as a result several banks have to be [[Bailout|bailed out]] by the government.<ref name="gb"/> Banks' solvency issues and asset deterioration seriously damaged investor confidence. Meanwhile, liquidity shortage tightened credits going to production sectors. As a result, economies worldwide slowed and international trade declined. Governments and [[central bank]]s responded with unprecedented [[fiscal stimulus]], [[monetary policy]] expansion and institutional bailouts.<ref name="sbn">Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, Elias Papaioannou and Fabrizio Perri (2012). Global banks and crisis transmission. Journal of International Economics.</ref>
==See also==
* [[Asset-backed security]]
* [[Financial crisis of 2007–2010]]
* [[Great Recession]]
* [[Structured investment vehicle]]
* [[Subprime mortgage crisis]]
* [[Systemic risk]]


==References==
==References==

Revision as of 20:29, 26 June 2013

Asset-backed commercial paper program (ABCP program, ABCP Conduit or Conduit) is set up as a program that issues short-term liabilities, commercial papers called asset-backed commercial papers (ABCPs), to finance medium- to long-term assets.[1] In terms of terminology, ABCP usually refers to asset-backed commercial paper, while ABCP conduit (or conduit) the program. The maturities of ABCP range up to 270 days but average about 30 days.[2][3] Like banks, ABCP programs provide liquidity and maturity transformation services.[2] Because of this structure, ABCP conduits are considered to be part of the Shadow banking system.[4] A common and prominent feature of many ABCP programs is that they were created by banks to fund bank assets in an off-balance sheet way, possibly to avoid regulatory capital requirements.[2] Due to this character, ABCP is blamed to be one of the reasons of the 2008–09 global financial crises.

History

ABCP programs first appeared in the mid-1980s. Initially, ABCP conduits were primarily sponsored by major commercial banks as a means of providing trade receivable financing to their corporate customers. Over the past decade, ABCP programs have grown to serve a wide variety of needs such as: asset-based financing for companies that cannot access the commercial paper market, warehousing assets prior to security issuance, investing in rated securities for arbitrage profit, providing leverage to mutual funds, and off-balance sheet funding of bank assets.[5]

Above all these service types, ABCP programs are commonly used by banks to free up their regulatory capitals by moving the seemingly safe assets off their balance sheet. Traditionally, banks keep everything on their balance sheet and owners of the bank have to hold a certain amount of equity to meet the capital requirement. This means if a bank wants to invest in a large new project, i.e. increase its asset largely, it has to increase owners' equity proportionality. Moving such project off bank's balance sheet eliminates the need of increasing equity. Through setting up ABCP conduits, banks can fund assets all by short-term liabilities.

In general, any asset class that has been funded in the term market has been funded in a conduit, and there are a wide variety of assets that are unique to the conduit market, however, at the time of 2007, the major asset of most ABCP programs is asset-backed security backed by residential mortgages.[5]

As of September 2001, there were approximately 280 active ABCP programs, with more than $650 billion in outstanding.[6] During the mid-2000s, ABCP saw a steady rise in popularity because of their high ratings from the perspective of investors and the low borrowing rates from companies who need money. Gradually, even more conservative investors, such as money market mutual funds and retirement funds began purchasing ABCP. This optimism pushed the outstanding of ABCP to $1.3 trillion by the time of July 2007.[1] At that time, ABCP was the largest money market instrument in the United States, following by Treasury Bills with about $940 billion outstanding.[1] However, this trend came to an abrupt end in August 2007.[1]

During 2007, as negative information about U.S. residential mortgages spreads out, securities backed with mortgages, including sub-prime mortgages, widely held by ABCP programs of financial firms globally, started to lose their value. ABCP investors started to worry about the value of the asset backing their ABCP and stopped rolling over their position. At the beginning, sponsor banks have enough liquid to pay off these liabilities, but lack of market confidence can create a subprime mortgage crisis.

On August 2007, the French bank BNP Paribas halted withdrawals from three funds invested in ABCP and suspended calculation of net asset values. Even though defaults on mortgages had been rising throughout 2007, the suspension of withdrawals by BNP Paribas has a profound effect on ABCP market. The interest rate spread of over-night ABCP and Federal funds rate increased from 10 basis points to 150 basis points within one day of announcement.

Subsequently, the ABCP market experienced a modern-day bank run. Several ABCP conduits fall victims to liquidity crisis, and so are their sponsor financial institutions.[1] Since banks only need to keep regulatory capital for on-balance sheet assets, and none for the assets funded by ABCP conduits, they get into huge trouble paying back investors who refuse to roll over their ABCP. Several major financial institutions collapsed in the following year because of solvency issues and have to be bailed out by government.[1] See Financial crisis of 2007–2008 for details on the crisis and see Great Recession for the recession triggered by the financial crisis.

In December 2007, ABCP outstanding dropped from $1.3 trillion to $833 billion.[1] By the end of 2008, there is no SIV left. As of March 2013, the outstanding of ABCP is about $300 billion.[7]

Structure

An ABCP conduit is set up by a sponsoring financial institution (henceforth, sponsor). The sole purpose of a conduit is to purchase and hold financial assets from a variety of asset sellers.[1] The conduit finances the assets by selling asset-backed commercial paper] to outside investors such as money market funds or other "safe asset" investors like retirement funds.[1]

Take the conduit Grampian as an example. Grampian is a conduit set up and managed by HBOS. HBOS's management responsibilities consist of selecting the assets (Airbus, mortgages, etc.) to be purchased by Grampian and issuing short-term ABCP in order to finance the assets (Airbus, mortgages, etc.). HBOS sells the ABCP to outside investors such as Fidelity and rolls over the ABCP at regular intervals.[1]

Structure of a ABCP conduit

As in banks, the maturity of assets in ABCP conduits generally is longer than the maturity of the liabilities. More than half of ABCP daily issuance has maturities of 1 to 4 days, referred to as "overnight", and the average maturity of outstanding paper is about 30 days.[2] ABCP programs regularly roll over their liabilities and use proceeds from new issuances to pay off maturing commercial paper. Loan and lease receivables, which are assets commonly purchased by ABCP conduits, likely have terms of 30 days or more, and while relatively short, are still longer than most ABCP.[1] Most of the conduit assets are medium- to long-term assets with maturities of three to five yours.[1]

Financial institution (sponsor)

The sponsors of the conduit play two roles: manage assets and provide liquidity. Sponsor types range from large U.S. commercial banks to non-bank institutions, like mortgage lenders and asset managers. Large U.S. banks have long sponsored ABCP programs, some smaller U.S. banks sponsor a very modest share. Foreign banks sponsor a substantial share of ABCP, about 40 percent in 2007. Non-bank institutions, such as mortgage lenders, finance companies, or asset managers, also sponsor a considerable share of the market. Programs sponsored by non-bank institutions grew more dramatically than other programs from 2004 to 2007, more than doubling in assets to $400 billion.[2] The ten largest sponsors as of January 2007 are:[1]

  1. Citigroup (U.S.)
  2. ABN AMRO (Netherlands)
  3. Bank of America (U.S.)
  4. HBOS Pls (U.K.)
  5. JP Morgan (U.S.)
  6. HSBC (U.K.)
  7. Deutsche Bank AG (Germany)
  8. Société Générale (France)
  9. Barclays Plc (U.K.)
  10. Rabobank (Netherlands)

Conduits can generate significant risks for the sponsor. The sponsor’s guarantee typically covers the conduit’s roll-over risk, which is the risk that a conduit cannot refinance maturing commercial paper, possibly because of a deterioration of conduit asset values. In that case, the sponsor has to assume the losses from lower asset values, because under the guarantee sponsors are required to repurchase assets at par. In exchange for assuming this risk, the sponsor receives the conduit profits.[1]

Types of guarantees

Conduit sponsors use four different types of guarantees which provide different levels of insurance to outside investors. The four types of guarantees, ranked from strongest to weakest, are full credit guarantees ("full credit"), full liquidity guarantees ("full liquidity"), extendible notes guarantees ("extendible notes"), and guarantees arranged via structured investment vehicles (SIV).[1]

Full credit

Full credit guarantees are guarantees that require the sponsor to pay off maturing asset-backed commercial paper independent of the conduit's asset values. From a regulatory perspective, full credit guarantees are considered equivalent to on-balance sheet financing, because they expose banks to the same risks as assets on the balance sheet. Therefore, if the bank offer full credit guarantee, the backing assets will be on the balance sheet, thus are included in the calculation of capital needed to meat capital requirement. In practice, these guarantees are infrequently used by financial institutions that have to satisfy bank capital requirements.[1]

Full liquidity

Full liquidity guarantees are similar to full credit guarantees with the main difference being that the sponsor only needs to pay off maturing asset-backed commercial paper if the conduit assets are not in default. Hence, there is a possibility that full liquidity guarantees expire before the asset-backed commercial paper matures. This form of guarantees is weaker than full credit, but from the bank's side, they can move these assets off the balance sheet.[1]

Extendible notes

Extendible notes guarantees are similar to full liquidity guarantees with the main difference being that the conduit issuer has the discretion to extend maturing commercial paper for a limited period of time (usually 60 days or less). By extending the maturity of the commercial paper, it is more likely that the conduit's assets are in default before the commercial paper matures. From the viewpoint of an outside investor, extendible notes guarantees are therefore riskier than full liquidity guarantees. This guarantee was used by weaker financial institutions and by conduits with higher quality assets.[1]

SIV

SIV guarantees are also similar to full liquidity guarantees with the main difference being that SIV guarantees only cover a share of the conduit liabilities (usually around 25%). Since SIV guarantees do not cover all conduit liabilities, they are considered partial insurance to outside investors. SIV guarantees were primarily used by commercial banks and other financial institutions to cover high quality assets.[1]

Asset types

The asset types that conduits invested in are mostly asset-backed securities (ABS), residential mortgages, commercial loans and CDOs. Most of the assets are AAA-rated, some holds un-rated assets generated by the sponsor financial institution.[1] The asset origins are mostly United States (68%), Germany (15%) and United Kingdom (10%).[8]

Outside investors

The outside investors are mostly risk sensitive investors like money market fund and retirement funds.

Benefits

Originally, banks set up ABCP conduits to finance only safe assets off-balance sheet. Since these assets are considered safe, it is socially optimal for banks to invest more at a lower cost. ABCP conduit provides a way to free up regulatory capital, and thus achieve higher efficiency. At the same time, since safe assets are moved out of balance sheet, policy makers can target regulatory capital requirements only on the risky assets, which is what remains on the balance sheet.

Costs

However, due to no capital requirement for off-balance sheet assets, ABCP conduits also induce excessive risk taking. For example, banks may spread their capital very thin, and invest in highly risky projects that they would not have invested absent the mitigating effects of ABCP conduit on regulatory capital requirements. Especially when the sponsor bank is big, ABCP induces high moral hazard. When good state realized, the risky project will yield very high returns, but when bad state realized, the big bank expect government to bail it out. Therefore, banks optimally take on more risk because it does not care about the losses that occur in those states of nature when it goes bankrupt. Creditors will be bailed out and the interest rate at which the bank can borrow is therefore insensitive to bankruptcy risk. This is called "risk shifting"—shifting the risk from banks to the public. Most likely, policy makers find it optimal to bail out the bank, but needless to say, it is socially very costly.

Risks

Most conduits minimize their credit risk by holding a diversified portfolio of high quality assets. Typically, they are restricted to purchasing AAA-rated assets or unrated assets of similar quality. Some conduits exclusively purchase unrated assets originated by their sponsoring financial institutions. Other conduits mostly purchase securitized assets originated by other financial institutions. Many conduits combine the two strategies by purchasing both securitized and un-securitized assets from several financial institutions.[1]

Outside investors consider asset-backed commercial paper a safe investment for three reasons. First, the pool of conduit assets is used as collateral to secure the asset-backed commercial paper. Second, the conduit's sponsor provides guarantees to the conduit, which ensures that the sponsor repays maturing ABCPs in case the conduit is unable to pay off the maturing paper itself. Third, ABCP is very short-term, so that investors can easily liquidate their investment by not rolling over maturing ABCPs.[1]

However, asset holdings of ABCP conduits, like at banks, are not transparent. While the vast majority of ABCP programs have credit ratings from the major rating agencies, credit support mechanisms vary and the specific assets held in the programs are not widely known. For example, some ABCP programs viewed their holdings to be 'proprietary' investment strategies and deliberately did not disclose. Thus, random events or concerns about an economic downturn can create uncertainty about asset values. This uncertainty is greater when less information is available about the assets.[2]

While ABCP programs are like banks, a key distinction, with important implications for financial stability, is that ABCP programs do not have explicit deposit insurance provided by the government. Most traditional ABCP programs are sponsored by commercial banks that provide explicit liquidity support.[2]

ABCP conduit induces regulatory arbitrage and excessive risk taking. With so few skin in the game, banks will increase their investments, and especially investments in risky projects with negative expected returns. The resulting high leverage and high risk will increase systemic risk of the financial system, which further impose huge risk on the broader economy.

Types

There are five principal types of ABCP program:[5]

General purpose multi-seller

The most traditional ABCP program is a multi-seller program, in which a conduit purchases receivables and loans from multiple firms. The sponsor is typically a financial institution that provides the conduit with a committed liquidity line, administers its daily operations, and sometimes also provides the conduit with credit enhancement through a letter of credit that absorbs credit losses. At the end of July 2007, just before the widespread turmoil, there were 98 multi-seller programs in the U.S. ABCP market with outstanding of $525 billion, about 45 percent of total ABCP outstanding.[2]

Credit arbitrage

These programs involve banks sponsoring conduits to finance long-term assets through a special purpose entity that has a lower regulatory capital charge than if the assets were held on balance sheet. The sponsor banks typically provide full liquidity support. By using off-balance sheet funding, commercial banks exploit regulatory capital arbitrage opportunities. In July 2007, there were 35 programs that accounted for about 13 percent of the U.S. ABCP market.[2]

SIV

SIVs fund highly rated securities. But unlike the credit arbitrage programs, SIVs do not have explicit agreements with their sponsoring banks for committed back-stop liquidity lines covering all their short-term liabilities. Instead SIVs relied on dynamic liquidity management strategies, which involved liquidating assets to pay investors if needed. At their peak in July 2007, there were 35 SIVs that accounted for $84 billion of U.S. ABCP. Some ABCP is issued by collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), sometimes called SIV-lites. CDOs are similar to SIVs in structure, but are not actively managed and tend to rely on explicit but only partial liquidity support. There were 36 ABCP CDO programs in July 2007, with ABCP outstanding of $47 billion.[2]

Single-seller

Single-seller programs involve a conduit that issues commercial paper backed by assets from only one originator, which frequently also sponsors the conduit. The majority of single-seller conduits mainly fund credit-card receivables, mortgages, mortgage-backed securities, or auto loans. Such programs tended not to have explicit liquidity support, but were thought to be implicitly supported by originators. In July 2007, there were 40 non-mortgage single-seller programs, about 11 percent of the U.S. ABCP market. There also were 11 mortgage single-seller programs that primarily warehoused mortgages prior to their securitization.[2]

Loan-backed

Loan-backed programs are bank-sponsored programs and fund direct loans to the bank's corporate customers. These loans are generally closely managed by the bank, and have a variety of covenants designed to reduce credit risk.[5]

Relation to 2008-09 global financial crises

Economists think that the main feature of many ABCP is that they were created by banks to fund bank assets in an off-balance sheet way, possibly to avoid regulatory capital requirements.[2] Thus the ABCP market may be inherently unstable and a source of systemic risk.[2]

Before the 2008-09 financial crises, the global financial system "manufactured" risk-less assets, totaling over $1.2 trillion, by selling short-term ABCP to risk-averse investors, predominantly U.S. money market funds, and investing the proceeds primarily in long-term U.S. assets.

As negative information about U.S. assets became apparent in August 2007, banks experienced difficulties in rolling over ABCP and as a result several banks have to be bailed out by the government.[8] Banks' solvency issues and asset deterioration seriously damaged investor confidence. Meanwhile, liquidity shortage tightened credits going to production sectors. As a result, economies worldwide slowed and international trade declined. Governments and central banks responded with unprecedented fiscal stimulus, monetary policy expansion and institutional bailouts.[9]

References

  1. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s t u v Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl and Gustavo Suarez (2010). Securitization Without Risk Transfer, September 2010, NBER Working Paper No. 15730
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang and Gustavo Suarez (2009). The evolution of a financial crisis: Panic in the asset-backed commercial paper market. Division of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board.
  3. ^ Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System. http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/cp/about.htm.
  4. ^ Pozsar, Zoltan, Tobias Adrian, Adam Ashcraft and Hayley Boesky (2012). Shadow Banking. Staff Report No. 458. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports
  5. ^ a b c d The Fundamentals of Asset-Backed Commercial Paper. Structured Finance Special Report. http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2010/mcm/pdf/rutan1.pdf
  6. ^ Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Explained. Fitch Ratings. http://people.stern.nyu.edu/igiddy/ABS/fitchabcp.pdf
  7. ^ Asset-backed Commercial Paper Outstanding. Federal Reserve Economic Data. http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/ABCOMP
  8. ^ a b Acharya, Viral, Philipp Schnabl(2010). Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances? Asset-Backed Commercial Paper during the Financial Crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58(1), 37-73.
  9. ^ Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, Elias Papaioannou and Fabrizio Perri (2012). Global banks and crisis transmission. Journal of International Economics.