Jump to content

Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Research83 (talk | contribs)
Research83 (talk | contribs)
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{*********
DEAR REVIEWER,

THANK YOU FOR YOUR ADVICE. HERE IS A BRIEF SUMMARY OF THE CHANGES I MADE IN RESPONSE TO IT:
- THE TEXT IN ALL SECTIONS HAS BEEN SHORTENED, IN SEVERAL CASES DRASTICALLY.
- MANY STATEMENTS ARE NOW SUPPORTED THROUGH WEBLINKS WITH RELEVANT INFORMATION.
- MANY TERMS (JARGON) ARE NOW CROSS-LINKED TO OTHER ARTICLES IN WIKIPEDIA OR TO OTHER WEBSITES.
- SELF-FLATTERING STATEMENTS HAVE BEEN REDUCED AS MUCH AS POSSIBLE (DELETED OR RE-WRITTEN IN A MORE NEUTRAL FORM), OR ARE NOW SUPPORTED BY EVIDENCE (WEBLINKS).
- WEBLINKS ARE ADDED FOR BOOKS AND THE MOST IMPORTANT (MUCH CITED) ARTICLES MENTIONED IN THE TEXT (NOT IN FOOTNOTES).

NOTE THAT I ADDED COMMENTS ABOUT WHAT I CHANGED WHEN EDITING EACH PART OF THE TEXT SEPARATELY, BUT I CANNOT SEE THESE COMMENTS ANYWHERE, WHICH IS THE REASON FOR PROVIDING THIS GENERAL SUMMARY OF CHANGES HERE AT THE BEGINNING.

PLEASE LET ME KNOW IF FURTHER WORK IS NEEDED.

THANK YOU FOR YOUR TIME.
JEROEN VAN DEN BERGH
********************}}

{{AFC submission|d|prof|declinets=20140514073116|decliner=Timtrent|ts=20140407192946|u=Research83|ns=11888}}
{{AFC submission|d|prof|declinets=20140514073116|decliner=Timtrent|ts=20140407192946|u=Research83|ns=11888}}
{{afc comment|1=When you submit an article for acceptance, please at least understand basic Wikipedia formatting and use that. Nothing prejudices a reviewer against an article faster than cleaning up a huge swathe of text prior to review, or post review. I haven;'t cleaned all of it up. Much needs ripping out. As an example, the huge tracts of text and papers and articles going into the minutiae of his work only serve to promote a faux-notability and disguise real notability. INdeed, they anmd the opening remarks are why I deem this an advertisement.
{{afc comment|1=When you submit an article for acceptance, please at least understand basic Wikipedia formatting and use that. Nothing prejudices a reviewer against an article faster than cleaning up a huge swathe of text prior to review, or post review. I haven;'t cleaned all of it up. Much needs ripping out. As an example, the huge tracts of text and papers and articles going into the minutiae of his work only serve to promote a faux-notability and disguise real notability. INdeed, they anmd the opening remarks are why I deem this an advertisement.

Revision as of 14:38, 10 July 2014

{{********* DEAR REVIEWER,

THANK YOU FOR YOUR ADVICE. HERE IS A BRIEF SUMMARY OF THE CHANGES I MADE IN RESPONSE TO IT: - THE TEXT IN ALL SECTIONS HAS BEEN SHORTENED, IN SEVERAL CASES DRASTICALLY. - MANY STATEMENTS ARE NOW SUPPORTED THROUGH WEBLINKS WITH RELEVANT INFORMATION. - MANY TERMS (JARGON) ARE NOW CROSS-LINKED TO OTHER ARTICLES IN WIKIPEDIA OR TO OTHER WEBSITES. - SELF-FLATTERING STATEMENTS HAVE BEEN REDUCED AS MUCH AS POSSIBLE (DELETED OR RE-WRITTEN IN A MORE NEUTRAL FORM), OR ARE NOW SUPPORTED BY EVIDENCE (WEBLINKS). - WEBLINKS ARE ADDED FOR BOOKS AND THE MOST IMPORTANT (MUCH CITED) ARTICLES MENTIONED IN THE TEXT (NOT IN FOOTNOTES).

NOTE THAT I ADDED COMMENTS ABOUT WHAT I CHANGED WHEN EDITING EACH PART OF THE TEXT SEPARATELY, BUT I CANNOT SEE THESE COMMENTS ANYWHERE, WHICH IS THE REASON FOR PROVIDING THIS GENERAL SUMMARY OF CHANGES HERE AT THE BEGINNING.

PLEASE LET ME KNOW IF FURTHER WORK IS NEEDED.

THANK YOU FOR YOUR TIME. JEROEN VAN DEN BERGH

                                        • }}
  • Comment: When you submit an article for acceptance, please at least understand basic Wikipedia formatting and use that. Nothing prejudices a reviewer against an article faster than cleaning up a huge swathe of text prior to review, or post review. I haven;'t cleaned all of it up. Much needs ripping out. As an example, the huge tracts of text and papers and articles going into the minutiae of his work only serve to promote a faux-notability and disguise real notability. INdeed, they anmd the opening remarks are why I deem this an advertisement.
    You also have a basic and profound misunderstanding of references and their purpose here. We don't actually care about works he has written (used as references). We care about what others have written about him. We need significant coverage in WP:RS, and not a list of primary sources which detail his prolific research work.
    The list of PhD students is very pleasant, but must go. This is again material that appears to be an advertisement. Other such lists must be pruned. If he had written 1,000 books this would not be the place to list them. Wikipedia is not a directory
    Consider your writing style. It needs to be far briefer and far flatter. We require WP:NPOV, and we also deprecate puffery and equivocation and dissembling
    There is a lot to do here, all of it good. Please go to work with a will Fiddle Faddle 07:31, 14 May 2014 (UTC)

File:Picture Jeroen van den Bergh.JPG
Picture Jeroen van den Bergh

Jeroen C.J.M. van den Bergh (born 1st of August 1965) is an environmental economist of Dutch origin who currently works and lives in Spain. He is ICREA[1] Research Professor at Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona and Deputy Director for Research of its Institute of Environmental Science and Technology, and professor of Environmental and Resource Economics at VU University Amsterdam. He undertakes research on the interface of economics, innovation research, energy analysis and climate studies. He has advised the Dutch government (ministries of economics, environment and transport) and various international organizations (UNEP, UNIDO, EU, OECD, WB) and NGOs about environmental, energy and climate policies. He was a member of the The Dutch Energy Council, and of the Advisory Council of the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency. He has supervised more than 20 PhD theses, and published 16 books and more than 150 articles in refereed international journals. His work is much cited[2] and received several prizes, including two major environmental awards. In terms of production and citations he belongs to the top 2% economists in Europe[3], and is the highest ranked environmental economist of Spain.

Academic career

Jeroen van den Bergh was born in 1965 in Ossendrecht (Noord-Brabant, The Netherlands), graduated in 1983 in Athenaeum Beta (cum laude) from Mollerlyceum in Bergen op Zoom, and did a Propedeuse (cum laude) and Master (“Doctoraal”) in Econometrics and Operations Research at Tilburg University. In 1988 he moved to Amsterdam to work at Vrije Universiteit (VU University Amsterdam) on a PhD thesis titled “Dynamic models for sustainable development” (defense December 1991, supervisors P. Nijkamp and J.B. Opschoor). His thesis developed a range of system-dynamic models to study sustainability policies and environmental limits to economic growth. During his postdoc period he broadened his research to include topics like environment and trade, transport and environment, spatial equilibrium modelling with environment, materials-product chains, and meta-analysis. His work is on the boundary of mainstream (Environmental economics) and heterodox (Ecological economics) approaches, as he considers each approach to contribute something useful to our understanding of effective solutions to environmental problems.[4]

In July 1997 he was appointed as full professor of Environmental Economics in the Faculty of Economics and Business Administration at VU University Amsterdam (VUA), and in January 2002 additionally as full professor of ‘Nature, Space and Water’ in the Institute for Environmental Studies of VUA. In this period he further extended his research to include environmental innovation, transition studies, behavioral and evolutionary economics, and economics of climate change. In September 2007 van den Bergh moved to Spain to become ICREA[5] Professor at Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona (UAB). He currently is deputy director responsible for research of the Institute of Environmental Science and Technology (Institut de Ciència i Tecnologia Ambientals) of UAB. In addition, he has a full professorship in Environmental and Resource Economics at VU University Amsterdam.

Main activities

Van den Bergh has made original contributions to a range of research themes, including the benefits and instruments of climate policy, environmental innovation and sustainability transitions, economic growth versus the environment, and environmental policy informed by economic psychology and behavioral economics. He has a particular interest in applying evolutionary economics to understand environmental problems and their solutions. He has published more than 150 articles in renowned journals in each of aforementioned areas, is co-author of seven monographs and editor of nine books. His work involves various types of applied mathematical modelling, econometric-statistical analysis, conceptual studies, policy analyses, and critical examinations of indicators and methods.

Van den Bergh is/was a member of the editorial board of more than ten international journals, and is editor of the book series “Advances in Ecological Economics” of Edward Elgar Publishers (UK). He was (invited) editor of the section “Environmental Economics” in the Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems (UNESCO, 2001). He is editor-in-chief of the Elsevier journal Environmental Innovation & Societal Transitions. He was a member of the Advisory Council of the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency and a member of the Energy Council, the main advisory board on energy issues to the Dutch government, as well as chairman of various research programs in the areas of social and environmental sciences within the Netherlands Organization for Scientific Research (NWO). He is member of the scientific advisory board of the Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO).

Van den Bergh is the editor of the Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics (1999, Edward Elgar Publ., 1300 pages), awarded “Outstanding Academic Title” in 2000 by Choice Magazine[6]. This is generally regarded not only as a complete overview of the field of environmental and resource economics but also as a constructive synthesis of mainstream and heterodox approaches.[7] Two other important books result from projects undertaken under his guidance: Spatial Ecological-Economic Analysis for Wetland Management(2004, Cambridge University Press) with an integration of hydrology, ecology and economics, and Economics of Industrial Ecology (2005, The MIT Press) combining economics with energy and material flow analysis. These reflect his interest in multidisciplinary research. Last but not least, 23 researchers have successfully finished and defended a PhD/doctorate thesis under his supervision.

Among his most cited articles are a critique of the Ecological footprint[8], a contribution to the literature on the environmental Kuznets curve[9], one of the first studies on the impact of environmental policy differences between countries on international trade patterns[10], a critical assessment of monetary valuation of biodiversity[11], and the first synthetic article of the implications of bounded rationality for environmental policy theory.[12]

Research themes

Van den Bergh works or has worked on the following research themes:

Climate economics and policy

Over time, van den Bergh’s research is increasingly focused on climate change, as he thinks this represent the most important and difficult environmental challenge we face. He developed an alternative for cost-benefit analysis in "climate economics", which resulted in 12 perspectives strengthening the case for a stringent climate policy.[13] In a recent article in Nature Climate Change he calculated a lower bound to the social cost of carbon (SCC) of US$125.[14] In another study, he assessed the responsibilities for historical cumulative contributions to CO2 in the atmosphere by countries, from which it follows that China will around 2050 become the largest historical emitter of CO2.[15]

A core concern of van den Bergh’s research is identifying effective climate policy, namely by undertaking systemic analyses and examining unintended, indirect effects of energy and climate policies. He has studied the adequate combination of environmental regulation (standards, taxes or tradable permits) and innovation policies (renewable energy subsidies) to avoid problems of escape routes like “energy rebound”[16], “carbon leakage”, “green paradox” (oil market responses to climate policy) and “shifting of environmental problems”.[17] The general lesson of his research is that while a partial viewpoint on environmental policy is attractive as it keeps things simple, only a systems perspective identifies really effective solutions for energy scarcity and climate change. His article in Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America summarizes his views on an effective energy-climate policy package.[18] Recently, he showed that re-spending rebound in terms of energy or CO2 emissions is a serious concern for both rich countries and emerging economies.[19].

With Dr. Wouter Botzen from VUA he has studied insurance against climate change impacts, notably related to flooding risks. Here the specific combination of bounded rationality and extreme events has been confronted with econometric studies of data, obtained with choice experiments, on individual decision making under low-probability/high-impact risks.[20]

Economic growth versus the environment

In 1999 van den Bergh wrote an article classifying five main positions or viewpoints in the long-standing environment-versus-growth debate, namely the moralist, pessimist, technocrat, sceptic and optimist.[21]. He returned to this theme on various occasions, dealing with the connection between energy and growth[22], or proposing a new growth theory to study dematerialization.[23] He further investigated the implications of having to reduce the CO2 intensity of economic output worldwide with more than 80%, and the friction between climate and employment goals resulting from it.[24] In addition, he evaluated the fierce criticm levied at Lomborg's book The Skeptical Environmentalist which suggested that growth and environment are compatible as environmental problems are exaggerated.[25]

A prize-winning and much cited paper has proposed the existence of a so-called “GDP paradox”[26] It explains why despite the widely accepted criticism of GDP as a reliable indicator of progress for rich countries, the majority of economists and politicians continues to give unconditional support to it. He participated in the recent debate on “de-growth”, expressing criticism of this goal and proposing an alternative, namely “a-growth”: this denotes being indifferent about economic growth in rich countries, which follows logically from accepting the shortcomings of GDP (per capita) as an indicator of social welfare. His plea for a-growth reflects a new, refreshing position next to the polarized pro- and anti-growth views in the long-standing debate on growth-versus-environment.[27] In a related article he argued that ignoring GDP as a progress indicator would open up new policy directions to respond to both climate change and the financial-economic crisis.[28]

Evolutionary economics, environmental innovation and sustainability transition

Van den Bergh’s main theoretical achievement is perhaps the integration of evolutionary economics and modelling with environmental economics and sustainability transition studies.[29] [30] This has resulted in a large number of technical, conceptual and policy papers, many with his PhD students, as well as a book Evolutionary Economics and Environmental Policy: Survival of the Greenest. Evolutionary thinking and modelling is becoming popular in the social sciences as it allows addressing social, economic and technological complexity characterized by diversity of actors, groups, firms, technologies, products and ideas. The change in this diversity is driven by technical and organizational innovations combined with multiple selection forces, including markets and public policies.[31] Van den Bergh is internationally recognized as one of the main researchers working on the interface of evolutionary and environmental economics.[32]

His first modelling work in this area, with Noailly and Withagen, focused on the exploitation of renewable resources like fisheries, agriculture and irrigation.[33] He further wrote on evolutionary microfoundations of economics[34], coevolution of behavior and institutions[35], and group selection to explain socio-economic phenomena.[36] In addition, he developed a general theory of policy based on evolutionary principles, addressing both normative and positive aspects.[37] In a much cited article he applied evolutionary economics to analyse policy packages aimed at stimulating a transition to sustainable energy.[38] One formal model assessed the effectiveness, in comparison with environmental taxes, of providing information to consumers and awarding prizes to innovators, so as to draw attention to green alternatives[39] Another study elaborated the famous model by Brian Arthur explaining lock-in of undesirable technologies and adapted this to an environmentally relevant transition setting by testing for the impact of modular, recombinant innovation (like hybrid cars) on the feasibility and speed of a sustainability transition.[40]

Possibly his most important, and much cited, contribution in this area is the notion of “optimal technological diversity”, which combines elements of neoclassical and evolutionary economics.[41] He formalised this in a mathematical model that accounts for three dimensions of diversity (inspired by Stirling), increasing returns to scale and recombinant innovation. This provides strategies for renewable energy that make an optimal trade-off between scale advantages - focusing on few energy technologies - and diversity advantages - keeping promising technological options open.

He further studied policies for "environmental and climate innovations". This includes an empirical evaluation of the success and failure factors behind all major transport sustainability initiatives undertaken in the Netherlands in the past decades.[42] One article identifies the peculiarities of environmental/climate innovations as compared with traditional, commercial innovations, and their implications for effective policies.[43] A recent article examines how to allocate public subsidies between R&D and market diffusion for renewable energy so as to promote its long run success.[44]

Behavioral economics and environmental policy

Closely related to evolutionary economics is his interest in behavioral economics, i.e. theories of human bounded rationality and other-regarding (or social) behavior. The connection between behavioral and evolutionary economics is that the first provides an individual perspective on behavior while the latter studies (market and network) interactions of many individuals in populations of heterogeneous agents. Such an approach provides more realism in environmental policy analysis. He wrote an early, much cited article on behavioral economics and environmental policy.[45] He has applied behavioral economics, among others, to better understand insurance against climate change disasters[46], and barriers to and opportunities for an international climate agreement.[47] In the latter case he finds that reframing of climate change and policy needs more attention. The likelihood of a climate agreement was examined here for negative frames (called “Gore” and “Bush”) and positive frames (called “Nordhaus” and “Stern”, after two famous climate economists). One conclusion drawn is that climate negotiations might benefit from the involvement of (economic) psychologists.

Spatial and international aspects of environmental policy

Van den Bergh has written much on the spatial and international dimensions of environmental policy. With van Beers he undertook one of the first (and much cited) studies to assess the impact of differences in environmental policy between countries on trade and location. One methodological problem tackled here was the construction of input and output indicators to capture the strength of environmental policy in various countries.[48] In addition, he addressed the notion of "spatial sustainability", that is, the best spatial organization of the economy to contribute to sustainability. This included a much cited, systematic assessment of the ecological footprint method.[49] Addressing the broader theme - spatial sustainability in the context of endogenous firm and household locations, transport and international trade - has given rise to a policy-relevant extension of the famous agglomeration model by Paul Krugman with environmental factors.[50]

Economics of biodiversity and terrestrial/marine ecosystem management

Van den Bergh has further worked on various projects related to biodiversity policy and ecosystem valuation. With Barendregt and Gilbert he developed a very ambitious spatial economic-hydroecological modelling approach to evaluate land use impacts in a large wetlands area in the centre of the Netherlands.[51] This is reported in detail in the book Spatial Ecological-Economic Analysis for Wetland Management (Cambridge University Press). Another study showed that the well-known Weitzman criterion for biodiversity protection (The Noah's ark problem) alters when not only genetic but also ecological information (about ecosystem and foodweb relations) is taken into account.[52]

An article with Nunes considered all the arguments in favour and against monetary valuation of biodiversity.[53] With Maestre et al. he studied unintended indirect (rebound) effects of biodiversity policy which make this policy less effective than possible.[54] Another study presented a balanced environmental-economic assessment of genetic modification of agricultural crops.[55] A study with Hoekstra developed an ambitious mathematical model to consider optimal exploitation (harvesting) of a species (e.g. fisheries) if another species with a high conservation value ecologically interacts with it.[56] He further applied several valuation methods (contingent valuation and choice experiment techniques) to assess the values of ecosystems and their management.[57] His most cited paper in this area with Turner and others presented a method for economic assessment of ecosystem complexity, focusing on wetlands.[58]

He further undertook valuation and modelling of changes in marine ecosystems. A book Modeling and Policy Analysis of Exploited Marine Ecosystems, combining biology and economics, collects his theoretical and applied studies with a research team on fisheries management in the Dutch Wadden Sea. Recently, he worked on the economics of ocean acidification in the Mediterranean Sea due an increased CO2 concentration of the atmosphere.[59] In a recent article with Gagern in PLoS One trade data were analysed to estimate actual fishing weight, providing empirical evidence for the suspicion that there is structural overfishing of (Bluefin) tuna in various parts of the world.[60]

Materials flows, mass balance and recycling in economic analysis

Van den Bergh’s early work addressed the integration of materials flow accounting and economic modelling, physical-technical limits to growth, and substitution of materials by other production factors.[61] He wrote a fundamental article on economic production functions that are consistent with mass balance.[62] With Bouman and others he undertook a much cited methodological comparison of distinct approaches to integrate materials flow analysis with economics.[63] Rutger Hoekstra and he developed various input-output model techniques to deal with material flows and their factor decomposition.[64] Together with Robert Ayres he developed a much cited alternative theory of economic growth to study dematerialization of the economy. His book Economic of Industrial Ecology (The MIT Press) provides an overview of models and empirical tools to integrate physical flows and economics.

Remaining themes: world population limit, perverse subsidies, and aggregate environmental indicators

It is not the intention to give a complete account here of topics addressed by van den Bergh. Three more, however, deserve brief mention. First, he performed a meta-analysis of all 69 quantitative studies that estimated a limit to the world population.[65] This produced a meta-estimate of the limit equal to 7.2 billion people (compare with the actual level here: World Population). Second, with van Beers he quantified various environmentally damaging off-budget (i.e. “hidden”) subsidies.[66] Finally, in line with his criticisms of the GDP as a welfare indicator, and of the footprint as an environmental indicator, with Pillarisetti he assessed and compared a number of other proposals for aggregate environmental indicators, such as Genuine savings, the Environmental Sustainability Index, the Sustainable Society Index and the Happy Planet Index.[67]

Acclaim and awards

According to the largest bibliographic database on economists, IDEAS/RePEc, by various criteria, van den Bergh belongs to the top 1% economists in Spain and the top 2% in the EU and Europe, and is the highest ranked environmental economist in Spain. His work has generated many responses, illustrated by 2060/2656/9300 citations, and an h-index of 23/26/50 (ISI Web of Science/Scopus/Google Scholar), which represent high scores in the social sciences. In addition, 11 of his articles are reprinted in collections with "classic articles”.[68] He is an elected member of the Academia Europaea (since October 2010). He received prizes for a book and two articles, and two general environmental science prizes: He is co-winner of 2012 Chris Freeman Award of the European Association for the Study of Science and Technology, for contributing an article on "Evolutionary theorizing and modeling of sustainability transitions" to a special issue of the journal Research Policy 41(6) on "sustainability transitions". His article “The GDP Paradox”, published in Journal of Economic Psychology 30(2), was awarded a "Citation of Excellence" by the Emerald Management Reviews in 2010.[69] His Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics was selected in the category “Outstanding Academic Title” in 2000 by Choice Magazine.[70] He received the 2011 Sant Jordi Environmental Prize ("Premi Sant Jordi de Medi Ambient 2011") in recognition of contributions to the field of environmental and resource economics.[71] And he was awarded the 2002 Royal/Shell Prize for research on ‘Sustainable Development, Environment and Resources’.[72]

Published books

Monographs

1. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (1991), Dynamic Models for Sustainable Development, Thesis Publishers, Amsterdam, 274 pages (Ph.D. thesis). 2. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (1996), Ecological Economics and Sustainable Development: Theory, Methods and Applications, Edward Elgar Publ., Aldershot, UK, (2nd print), 312 pages. 3. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, K.J. Button, P. Nijkamp en G.J. Pepping (1997), Meta-analysis in Environmental Economics. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, 219 pages. 4. P.A.L.D. Nunes, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and P. Nijkamp (2003). The Ecological Economics of Biodiversity: Methods and Applications. Edward Elgar Publ., Cheltenham, UK, 165 pages. 5. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, A. Barendregt and A. Gilbert (2004). Spatial Ecological-Economic Analysis for Wetland Management: Modelling and Scenario Evaluation of Land Use, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 254 pages. 6. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, J. Hoekstra, R. Imeson, P. Nunes and A. de Blaeij (2006). Economic Modeling and Policy Analysis of Exploited Marine Ecosystems. Springer, Dordrecht, 263 pages. 7. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, A. Faber, A.M. Idenburg and F.H. Oosterhuis (2007). Evolutionary Economics and Environmental Policy: Survival of the Greenest. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 180 pages.

Edited volumes

1. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and J. van der Straaten (eds.) (1994), Toward Sustainable Development: Concepts, Methods and Policy, Island Press, Washington D.C., USA, 287 pages. 2. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, P. Nijkamp and P. Rietveld (eds.) (1996), Recent Advances in Spatial Equilibrium Modeling: Methodology and Applications. Springer, Berlin, 391 pages (based on own workshop). 3. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and J. van der Straaten (eds.) (1997), Economy and Ecosystems in Change: Analytical and Historical Approaches. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, 400 pages. 4. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and M.W. Hofkes (eds.) (1998), Theory and Implementation of Economic Models for Sustainable Development. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, 327 pages (based on own workshop). 5. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (ed.) (1999), Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics. Edward Elgar Publ., Cheltenham, UK, 1328 pages (awarded “Outstanding Academic Title” by Choice Magazine, January 2001; 2nd print as paperback). 6. R.K. Turner, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and R. Brouwer (eds.) (2003), Managing Wetlands: An Ecological Economics Approach. Edward Elgar Publ., Cheltenham, UK, 328 pages. 7. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and M.A. Janssen (eds.) (2005). Economics of Industrial Ecology: Use of Materials, Structural Change and Spatial Scales. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, USA, 448 pages (based on own research projects and workshop). 8. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, K.J. Button and P. Nijkamp (eds.) (2007). Environmental Planning. Classics in Planning, vol. 8. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 38 chapters, 636 pages. 9. J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and F. Bruinsma (eds.) (2008). Managing the Transition to Renewable Energy: Theory and Macro/Regional Practice. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 385 pages (based on a special session at a conference).

References

  1. ^ Catalan Institution for Research and Advanced Studies
  2. ^ E.g., http://scholar.google.nl/citations?user=BUU8dOsAAAAJ&hl=en&oi=ao
  3. ^ http://ideas.repec.org/top/
  4. ^ J. van den Bergh (2000). Ecological Economics: Themes, approaches, and differences with environmental economics. Regional Environmental Change 3(1): 13-23. J. van den Bergh (2010). Externality or sustainability economics? Ecological Economics 69(11): 2047-2052.
  5. ^ Catalan Institution for Research and Advanced Studies Research
  6. ^ http://www.ala.org/acrl/choice/outstanding
  7. ^ See the book review by Frank Convery, past president of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists: http://link.springer.com/article/10.1023/A%3A1011135203993
  8. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and H. Verbruggen (1999), Spatial sustainability, trade and indicators: an evaluation of the ‘ecological footprint’, Ecological Economics 29(1): 63-74.
  9. ^ S.M. de Bruyn, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and J.B. Opschoor (1998), Economic growth and emissions: reconsidering the empiricial basis of environmental Kuznets curves. Ecological Economics 25: 161-175.
  10. ^ C. van Beers and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (1997), An empirical multi-country analysis of the impact of environmental regulations on foreign trade. Kyklos 50: 29-46.
  11. ^ P. Nunes and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2001). Monetary valuation of biodiversity: sense or nonsense? Ecological Economics 39(2): 203-222.
  12. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, A. Ferrer-i-Carbonell en G. Munda (2000), Alternative models of individual behaviour and implications for environmental policy. Ecological Economics 32(1): 43-61.
  13. ^ J. van den Bergh (2010), Safe climate policy is affordable – 12 reasons, Climatic Change 101(3): 339–385. http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs10584-009-9719-7#
  14. ^ J. van den Bergh and W. Botzen (2014), A lower bound to the social cost of CO2 emissions. Nature Climate Change 4: 253-258. http://www.nature.com/nclimate/journal/v4/n4/full/nclimate2135.html
  15. ^ Botzen, W.J.W., J.M. Gowdy and J. van den Bergh (2008), Cumulative CO2 emissions: shifting international responsibilities for climate debt, Climate Policy 8: 569–576. http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.3763/cpol.2008.0539
  16. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2011). Energy conservation more effective with rebound policy. Environmental and Resource Economics 48(1): 43-58. http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs10640-010-9396-z#
  17. ^ van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. (2012). Effective climate-energy solutions, escape routes and peak oil. Energy Policy 46: 530–536. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421512003229
  18. ^ J. van den Bergh (2013). Policies to enhance economic feasibility of a sustainable energy transition. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sciences USA (PNAS) 110(7): 2436-2437.
  19. ^ Antal, M., and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2013). Re-spending rebound: A macro-level assessment for OECD countries and emerging economies. Energy Policy 68: 585-590. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421513011233
  20. ^ W.J.W. Botzen and J. van den Bergh (2011), Monetary valuation of insurance against flood risk under climate change, International Economic Review 53(3): 1005-1025.
  21. ^ J. van den Bergh and R.A. de Mooij (1999). An assessment of the growth debate. In: J. van den Bergh, (ed.). Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 643-655. See also R.A. de Mooij and J. van den Bergh (2002), Growth and the environment in Europe: a guide to the debate, Empirica 29(2): 79-91.
  22. ^ Ayres, R.U., J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, D. Lindenberger and B. Warr (2013). The underestimated contribution of energy to economic growth. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 27: 79-88.
  23. ^ Ayres, R.U., and J. van den Bergh (2005), A theory of economic growth with material/energy resources and dematerialization: interaction of three growth mechanisms, Ecological Economics 55(1): 96-118.
  24. ^ Antal, M., and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2013). Macroeconomics, financial crisis and the environment: Strategies for a sustainability transition. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 6: 47-66.
  25. ^ J. van den Bergh (2010), An assessment of Lomborg’s “The Skeptical Environmentalist” and the ensuing debate, Journal of Environmental Sciences 7(1): 23-52.
  26. ^ J. van den Bergh (2009), The GDP Paradox, Journal of Economic Psychology 30(2): 117–135.
  27. ^ J. van den Bergh (2010), Environment versus growth – A criticism of “degrowth” and a plea for “a-growth”? Ecological Economics 70(5): 881-890.
  28. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2010). Relax about GDP growth: Implications for climate and crisis policies. Journal of Cleaner Production 18(6): 540-543.
  29. ^ see Technological_transitions and Transition management (governance)
  30. ^ van den Bergh, J. (2007), Evolutionary thinking in environmental economics, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 17(5): 521-549. 127. K. Safarzynska, K. Frenken and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2012). Evolutionary theorizing and modelling of sustainability transitions. Research Policy 41: 1011-1024.
  31. ^ K. Safarzynska and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2010). Evolutionary modelling in economics: A survey of methods and building blocks. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 20(3): 329-373. K. Safarzynska and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2011). Beyond replicator dynamics: Innovation-selection dynamics and optimal diversity. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 78(3): 229-245.
  32. ^ See search results of the combination of terms "evolutionary economics" and "environmental economics" on Google Scholar
  33. ^ J. Noailly, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and C.A. Withagen (2003). Evolution of harvesting strategies: replicator and resource dynamics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 13(2): 183-200. Noailly, J., C. Withagen and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2007). Evolution of social norms in a common-pool resource game. Environmental and Resource Economics 36(1): 113-141.
  34. ^ J. van den Bergh and J.M. Gowdy (2003). The microfoundations of macroeconomics: an evolutionary perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics 27(1): 65-84.
  35. ^ J. van den Bergh and S. Stagl (2003), Coevolution of economic behaviour and institutions: towards a theory of institutional change, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 13 (3): 289-317.
  36. ^ J. van den Bergh and J.M. Gowdy (2009). A group selection perspective on economic behavior, institutions and organizations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 72(1): 1-20.
  37. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and G. Kallis (2013). A survey of evolutionary policy: normative and positive dimensions: Journal of Bioeconomics 15(3): 281-303.
  38. ^ Safarzynska, K., and J. van den Bergh (2010), Demand-supply coevolution with multiple increasing returns: Policy analysis for unlocking and system transitions, Technological Forecasting and Social Change 77(2): 297–317. See also K. Safarzynska and J. van den Bergh (2011), Industry evolution, rational agents and the transition to sustainable electricity production, Energy Policy 39(10): 6440-52. And K. Safarzynska and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2013). An evolutionary model of energy transitions with interactive innovation-selection dynamics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 23: 271-293.
  39. ^ Nannen, V., and J. van den Bergh (2010), Policy instruments for evolution of bounded rationality: Application to climate-energy problems, Technological Forecasting and Social Change 77(1): 76–93.
  40. ^ P. Zeppini and J. van den Bergh (2011), Competing recombinant technologies for environmental innovation: Extending Arthur’s model of lock-in, Industry and Innovation 18 (3): 317–334.
  41. ^ J. van den Bergh (2008), Optimal diversity: Increasing returns versus recombinant innovation, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 68(3-4): 565-580. See also S.T.A. van den Heuvel and J. van den Bergh (2009), Multilevel assessment of diversity, innovation and selection in the solar photovoltaic industry, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 20(1): 50-60. And K. Safarzynska and J. van den Bergh (2011). Beyond replicator dynamics: Innovation-selection dynamics and optimal diversity. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 78(3): 229-245. And P. Zeppini and J. van den Bergh (2013), Optimal diversity in investments with recombinant innovation, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 24: 141-156.
  42. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, E.S. van Leeuwen, F.H. Oosterhuis, P. Rietveld, and E.T. Verhoef (2007). Social learning by doing in sustainable transport innovations: ex-post analysis of common factors behind successes and failures. Research Policy 36: 247-259.
  43. ^ J. van den Bergh (2013), Environmental and climate innovation: Limitations, policies and prices, Technological Forecasting and Social Change 80(1):11-23. See also J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, B. Truffer and G. Kallis (2011). Environmental innovation and societal transitions: Introduction and overview. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions 1(1): 1-23.
  44. ^ Koseoglu, N.M., J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and J. Subtil Lacerda (2013). Allocating subsidies to R&D or to market applications of renewable energy? Balance and geographical relevance. Energy for Sustainable Development 17: 536-545.
  45. ^ J. van den Bergh, A. Ferrer-i-Carbonell, and G. Munda (2000), Alternative models of individual behaviour and implications for environmental policy, Ecological Economics 32(1): 43-61. A recent update is E. Gsottbauer, and J. van den Bergh (2010), Environmental policy theory given bounded rationality and other-regarding preferences, Environmental and Resource Economics 49(2): 263-304. 147. See also J. van den Bergh (2008), Environmental regulation of households? An empirical review of economic and psychological factors, Ecological Economics 66: 559-74.
  46. ^ W. Botzen, and J. van den Bergh (2009). Bounded rationality, climate risks and insurance: Is there a market for natural disasters? Land Economics 85(2): 266-279.
  47. ^ E. Gsottbauer and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2013). Bounded rationality and social interaction in negotiating a climate agreement. International Environmental Agreements 13: 225-249.
  48. ^ C. van Beers and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (1996), An overview of methodological approaches in the analysis of trade and environment. Journal of World Trade 30: 143-167. C. van Beers and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (1997), An empirical multi-country analysis of the impact of environmental regulations on foreign trade. Kyklos 50: 29-46. C. van Beers en J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2003). Environmental regulation impacts on international trade: aggregate and sectoral analyses with a bilateral trade flow model. International Journal of Global Environmental Issues 3(1): 14-29.
  49. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and H. Verbruggen (1999), Spatial sustainability, trade and indicators: an evaluation of the ‘ecological footprint’, Ecological Economics 29(1): 63-74. See further J. van den Bergh and F. Grazi (2010), On the policy relevance of ecological footprints, Environmental Science and Technology 44(13): 4843–4844. And for an update, Grazi, F., and J. van den Bergh (2014). Footprint policy? Land use as an environmental indicator. Journal of Industrial Ecology 18(1): 10-19.
  50. ^ F. Grazi, J. van den Bergh and P. Rietveld (2007), Welfare economics versus ecological footprint: modeling agglomeration, externalities and trade, Environmental and Resource Economics 38(1): 135-153. See also F. Grazi and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2008). Spatial organization, transport, and climate change: Comparing instruments of spatial planning and policy. Ecological Economics 67(4): 630-639. F. Grazi, J. van den Bergh and J.N. van Ommeren (2008), An empirical analysis of urban form, transport, and global warming, The Energy Journal 29(4): 97-122.
  51. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, A. Barendregt, A. Gilbert, M. van Herwijnen, P. van Horssen, P. Kandelaars en C. Lorenz (2001). Spatial economic-hydroecological modelling and evaluation of land use impacts in the Vecht Wetlands area. Environmental Modelling and Assessment 6(2): 87-100.
  52. ^ van der Heide, C.M., J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and E.C. van Ierland (2005). Extending Weitzman's economic ranking of biodiversity protection: combining ecological and genetic considerations. Ecological Economics 55: 218-223.
  53. ^ P. Nunes and J. van den Bergh (2001), Monetary valuation of biodiversity: sense or nonsense? Ecological Economics 39(2): 203-222.
  54. ^ S. Maestre, L. Calvet Calvet, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, I. Ring and P. Verburg (2012). Ineffective biodiversity policy due to five rebound effects. Ecosystem Services 1: 101-110.
  55. ^ J. van den Bergh en J.M. Holley (2002). An environmental-economic assessment of genetic modification of agricultural crops. Futures 34 (9-10): 802-822.
  56. ^ J. Hoekstra and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2005). Harvesting and conservation in a predator-prey system. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 29(6): 1097-1120.
  57. ^ See, e.g., P.A.L.D. Nunes, A.T. de Blaeij, and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2009). Decomposition of warm glow for multiple stakeholders: Stated choice valuation of shellfishery policy. Land Economics 85(3): 485-499.
  58. ^ R.K. Turner, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, T. Söderqvist, A. Barendregt, J. van der Straaten, E. Maltby, and E.C. van Ierland (2000), Ecological-economic analysis of wetlands: scientific integration for management and policy. Ecological Economics 35(1): 7-23.
  59. ^ L. Rodrigues, J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and A. Ghermandi (2013). Socio-economic impacts of ocean acidification in the Mediterranean Sea. Marine Policy 38:447-456.
  60. ^ A. Gagern and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2013). Trade-based estimation of Bluefin tuna catches in the Eastern Atlantic and Mediterranean, 2005-2011. PLoS ONE 8(7), e69959. 138.
  61. ^ J.van den Bergh and P. Nijkamp (1991), Operationalizing sustainable development: dynamic ecological-economic models, Ecological Economics 4: 11-33. J. van den Bergh (1993), A framework for modelling economy-environment-development relationships based on dynamic carrying capacity, materials balance and sustainable development feedback, Environmental and Resource Economics 3: 395-412. J. van den Bergh and P. Nijkamp (1994), Dynamic macro modelling and materials balance: Economic-environmental integration for sustainable development, Economic Modelling 11: 283-307. P. Kandelaars en J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2001). A Survey of material flows in economic models. International Journal of Sustainable Development 4(3): 282-303. P. Kandelaars and J. van den Bergh (1996), Materials-product chains: theory and an application, Environmental and Resource Economics 8: 97-118. P. van Beukering en J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2006). Modelling and analysis of international recycling between developed and developing countries. Resources, Conservation and Recycling 46: 1-26.
  62. ^ J. van den Bergh (1999), Materials, capital, direct/indirect substitution, and materials balance production functions, Land Economics 75 (4): 547-561.
  63. ^ M. Bouman, R. Heijungs, E. van der Voet, J. van den Bergh and G. Huppes (2000), Material flows and economic models: an analytical comparison of SFA, LCA and partial equilibrium models, Ecological Economics 32(2): 195-216.
  64. ^ R. Hoekstra and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2002). Structural I/O Decomposition Analysis of Material Flows through the Economy. Environmental and Resource Economics 23: 357-378. R. Hoekstra and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2006). The impact of structural change on physical flows in the economy: Forecasting and target analysis using structural decomposition analysis Land Economics 82(4): 582-601. Hoekstra, R., and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2006). Constructing physical input-output tables for environmental modeling and accounting: Framework and illustrations. Ecological Economics 59(3): 375-393.
  65. ^ J. van den Bergh and P. Rietveld (2004), Reconsidering the limits to world population: Meta-analysis and meta-prediction, BioScience 54(3): 195-204.
  66. ^ C. van Beers en J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2000). Perseverance of perverse subsidies and their impact on trade and the environment. Ecological Economics 36(3): 475 – 486. van Beers, C., J.C.J.M. van den Bergh, A. de Moor and F.H. Oosterhuis (2007). Determining the environmental effects of indirect subsidies: Integrated method and application to the Netherlands. Applied Economics 39: 2465-2482. Beers, C. van, and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2009). Environmental harm of hidden subsidies: Global warming and acidification. AMBIO 38(6): 339-341.
  67. ^ J.C.J.M. van den Bergh and D.B. van Veen-Groot (2001). Constructing aggregate environmental-economic indicators: a comparison of 12 OECD countries. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 4(1): 1-16. J.R. Pillarisetti and J.C.J.M. van den Bergh (2010). Sustainable nations: What do aggregate indexes tell us? Environment, Development and Sustainability 12(1): 49-62. J.R. Pillarisetti and J.C.J.M. van den bergh (2013). Aggregate indices for identifying environmentally responsible nations: an empirical analysis and comparison. International Journal of Environmental Studies 70(1): 140-150.
  68. ^ For details see his full CV at http://www.icrea.es/Web/ScientificStaff/JeroenvandenBergh--424
  69. ^ http://www.emeraldgrouppublishing.com/authors/literati/citations/awards.htm?id=2010&PHPSESSID=7uavvgk0s9t6i8pvang3cq0pe2
  70. ^ http://www.ala.org/acrl/choice/outstanding
  71. ^ http://www.iec.cat/activitats/noticiasencera.asp?id_noticies=247
  72. ^ http://www.nieuwsbank.nl/inp/2002/10/16/P158.htm