Jump to content

Tariff of Abominations: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Line 54: Line 54:


== Effects of the tariff ==
== Effects of the tariff ==
Faced with a reduced market for goods and pressured by hungry British abolitionists, the British reduced their imports of cotton from the United States, which hurt the South. The tariff forced the South to buy manufactured goods from U.S. manufacturers, mainly in the North, at a higher price, while southern states also faced a reduced income from sales of raw materials.
Faced with a reduced market for goods and pressured by hungry British abolitionists, the British reduced their imports of cotton from the United States, which hurt the South.  The tariff forced the South to buy manufactured goods from U. S. manufacturers, mainly in the North, at a higher price, while southern states also faced a reduced income from sales of raw materials.


Current Vice-President [[John C. Calhoun]] strongly opposed the tariff, anonymously authoring a pamphlet in December 1828 titled: The ''[[South Carolina Exposition and Protest]]'' in which he urged [[Nullification (U.S. Constitution)|nullification]] of the tariff within South Carolina. The South Carolina legislature, although it printed and distributed 5,000 copies of the pamphlet, took none of the legislative action that the pamphlet urged.
Current Vice-President [[John C. Calhoun]] strongly opposed the tariff, anonymously authoring a pamphlet in December 1828 titled: The ''[[South Carolina Exposition and Protest]]'' in which he urged [[Nullification (U.S. Constitution)|nullification]] of the tariff within South Carolina.  The South Carolina legislature, although it printed and distributed 5,000 copies of the pamphlet, took none of the legislative action that the pamphlet urged.


The expectation of the tariff’s opponents was that with the election of Jackson in 1828, the tariff would be significantly reduced.<ref>Remini, Robert V., ''Andrew Jackson and the Course of American Democracy, 1833-1845,'' pp. 136-137, (1984) ISBN 0-06-015279-6</ref><ref name=Niven>Niven, John. ''John C. Calhoun and the Price of Union'', pp. 135-137 >, William W., ''Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816-1836'', pg 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8</ref> When the Jackson administration failed to address its concerns, the most radical faction in South Carolina began to advocate that the state itself declare the tariff null and void within South Carolina.
The expectation of the tariff’s opponents was that with the election of Jackson in 1828, the tariff would be significantly reduced.<ref>Remini, Robert V., ''Andrew Jackson and the Course of American Democracy, 1833-1845,'' pp. 136–137, (1984) ISBN 0-06-015279-6</ref><ref name=Niven>Niven, John. ''John C. Calhoun and the Price of Union'', pp. 135–137 >, William W., ''Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816-1836'', p. 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8</ref> When the Jackson administration failed to address its concerns, the most radical faction in South Carolina began to advocate that the state itself declare the tariff null and void within South Carolina.


In Washington, an open split on the issue occurred between Jackson and Vice-President Calhoun.<ref name=Niven/><ref name=Freehling>Freehling, William W., ''Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816-1836'', pg 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8</ref><ref>Craven, Avery. ''The Coming of the Civil War'', p. 65 (1942) ISBN 0-226-11894-0</ref> On July 14, 1832, after Calhoun had resigned his office, Jackson signed into law the [[Tariff of 1832]] which made some reductions in tariff rates.
In Washington, an open split on the issue occurred between Jackson and Vice-President Calhoun.<ref name=Niven/><ref name=Freehling>Freehling, William W., ''Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816–1836'', p. 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8</ref><ref>Craven, Avery. ''The Coming of the Civil War'', p. 65 (1942) ISBN 0-226-11894-0</ref> On July 14, 1832, after Calhoun had resigned his office, Jackson signed into law the [[Tariff of 1832]] which made some reductions in tariff rates.


The reductions were too little for South Carolina. In November 1832 the state called for a convention. By a vote of 136 to 26, the convention overwhelmingly adopted an ordinance of nullification drawn by Chancellor [[William Harper (South Carolina)|William Harper]]. It declared that the tariffs of both 1828 and 1832 were unconstitutional and unenforceable in South Carolina. While the [[Nullification Crisis]] would be resolved in early 1833, tariff policy would continue to be a national political issue between the Democratic Party and the newly emerged Whig Party for the next twenty years.
The reductions were too little for South Carolina.&nbsp; In November 1832 the state called for a convention.&nbsp; By a vote of 136 to 26, the convention overwhelmingly adopted an ordinance of nullification drawn by Chancellor [[William Harper (South Carolina)|William Harper]].&nbsp; It declared that the tariffs of both 1828 and 1832 were unconstitutional and unenforceable in South Carolina.&nbsp; While the [[Nullification Crisis]] would be resolved in early 1833, tariff policy would continue to be a national political issue between the Democratic Party and the newly emerged Whig Party for the next twenty years.


==References==
==References==

Revision as of 20:19, 29 August 2010

The Tariff of 1828, was a protective tariff passed by the Congress of the United States on May 19, 1828 designed to to protect industry in the northern United States. It was labeled the Tariff of Abominations by its southern detractors because of the effects it had on the antebellum Southern economy and led to the Nullification Crisis.

The goal of the tariff was to protect industries in the northern United States which were being driven out of business by low-priced imported goods by putting a tax on them. The South, however, was harmed firstly by having to pay higher prices on goods the region did not produce, and secondly because reducing the importation of British goods made it difficult for the British to pay for the cotton they imported from the South.[1] The reaction in the South, particularly in South Carolina, would lead to the Nullification Crisis that began in late 1832.[2]

The Tariff marked the high point of US tariffs, being approached but not exceeded by the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act of 1930.[3]

Passage of the bill

The 1828 tariff was part of a series of tariffs that began after the War of 1812 and the Napoleonic Wars, when the blockade of Europe led British manufacturers to offer goods in America at prices American manufacturers often could not match.  The first protective tariff was passed by Congress in 1816, with tariff rates increased in 1824.  Southern states such as South Carolina contended that the tariff was unconstitutional and were opposed to the newer protectionist tariffs, but Western agricultural states favored them as well as New England’s industry.[4]

John C. Calhoun

In an elaborate scheme to prevent passage of still higher tariffs while at the same time appealing to Andrew Jackson’s supporters in the North, John C. Calhoun and other southerners joined them in crafting a tariff bill that would also weigh heavily on materials imported by the New England states.  It was believed that Adams’s supporters (the National Republicans, or as they would later be called, Whigs) in New England would uniformly oppose the bill for this reason and that the southern legislators could then withdraw their support, killing the legislation while blaming it on New England:

What that plan was, Calhoun explained very frankly nine years later, in a speech reviewing the events of 1828 and defending the course taken by himself and his southern fellow members.  A high-tariff bill was to be laid before the House.  It was to contain not only a high general range of duties, but duties especially high on those raw materials on which New England wanted the duties to be low.  It was to satisfy the protective demands of the Western and Middle States, and at the same time to be obnoxious to the New England members.  The Jackson men of all shades, the protectionists from the North and the free-traders from the South, were to unite in preventing any amendments; that bill, and no other, was to be voted on.  When the final vote came, the southern men were to turn around and vote against their own measure.  The New England men, and the Adams men in general, would be unable to swallow it, and would also vote against it.  Combined, they would prevent its passage, even though the Jackson men from the North voted for it.  The result expected was that no tariff bill at all would be passed during the session, which was the object of the southern wing of the opposition.  On the other hand, the obloquy of defeating it would be cast on the Adams party, which was the object of the Jacksonians of the North.  The tariff bill would be defeated, and yet the Jackson men would be able to parade as the true “friends of domestic industry.”[5]

Southern opponents generally felt that the protective features of tariffs were harmful to southern agrarian interests and claimed they were unconstitutional because they favored one sector of the economy over another.  New England importers and ship owners also had reason to oppose provisions targeting their industries—provisions inserted by Democratic Party legislators to coerce New Englanders to sink the legislation.

Those in Western states and manufacturers in the Mid-Atlantic States argued that strengthening the industrial capacity of the nation was in the interest of the entire country.  This same reasoning swayed two-fifths of U.S. Representatives in the New England states to vote for the tariff increase:

House Vote on Tariff of 1828 For Against
New England 16 23
Middle States (Mid-Atlantic) 57 11
West (OH, IN, IL, MO) 17 1
South (including LA) 3 50
Southwest (TN, KY) 12 9
Total 105 94

A substantial minority of New England Congressmen (41%) saw what they believed to be long-term national benefits of an increased tariff, and voted for it; they believed the tariff would strengthen the manufacturing industry nationally (see table).[6]

The Democratic Party had miscalculated: the New Englanders failed to sink the legislation, and their plan backfired.  This, despite the insertion of import duties by Democrats calculated to be unpalatable to New England industries, most specifically on raw wool imports, essential to the wool textile industry

The 1828 tariff was signed by President John Quincy Adams, although he realized it could weaken him politically.  In the Presidential election of 1828, Andrew Jackson defeated Adams with a popular tally of 647,286 votes and an electoral count of 178 as opposed to Adams’s 508,064 tally and 83 electoral votes.

Effects of the tariff

Faced with a reduced market for goods and pressured by hungry British abolitionists, the British reduced their imports of cotton from the United States, which hurt the South.  The tariff forced the South to buy manufactured goods from U. S. manufacturers, mainly in the North, at a higher price, while southern states also faced a reduced income from sales of raw materials.

Current Vice-President John C. Calhoun strongly opposed the tariff, anonymously authoring a pamphlet in December 1828 titled: The South Carolina Exposition and Protest in which he urged nullification of the tariff within South Carolina.  The South Carolina legislature, although it printed and distributed 5,000 copies of the pamphlet, took none of the legislative action that the pamphlet urged.

The expectation of the tariff’s opponents was that with the election of Jackson in 1828, the tariff would be significantly reduced.[7][8] When the Jackson administration failed to address its concerns, the most radical faction in South Carolina began to advocate that the state itself declare the tariff null and void within South Carolina.

In Washington, an open split on the issue occurred between Jackson and Vice-President Calhoun.[8][9][10] On July 14, 1832, after Calhoun had resigned his office, Jackson signed into law the Tariff of 1832 which made some reductions in tariff rates.

The reductions were too little for South Carolina.  In November 1832 the state called for a convention.  By a vote of 136 to 26, the convention overwhelmingly adopted an ordinance of nullification drawn by Chancellor William Harper.  It declared that the tariffs of both 1828 and 1832 were unconstitutional and unenforceable in South Carolina.  While the Nullification Crisis would be resolved in early 1833, tariff policy would continue to be a national political issue between the Democratic Party and the newly emerged Whig Party for the next twenty years.

References

  1. ^ "1816–1860: The Second American Party System and the Tariff", Tax History Museum. http://www.taxanalysts.com/museum/1816-1860.htm
  2. ^ Stampp, Kenneth. The Causes of the Civil War. 3rd Ed. New York, New York: Touchstone, 1991
  3. ^ WWS 543: Class notes, 2/17/10, Paul Krugman, February 16, 2010, Presentation, slide 4
  4. ^ [1] Taussig, F.W., The Tariff History of the United States, Part I, Fifth Edition, G. P. Putnam’s Sons, 1910, pages 70–74 (page 44–47 in .pdf format)
  5. ^ [2] Taussig, F.W., The Tariff History of the United States, Part I, Fifth Edition, G. P. Putnam’s Sons, 1910, pages 88, 89, (page 55 in .pdf format)
  6. ^ Bailey, Thomas A. The American Pageant D.C. Heath and Co. (1971)
  7. ^ Remini, Robert V., Andrew Jackson and the Course of American Democracy, 1833-1845, pp. 136–137, (1984) ISBN 0-06-015279-6
  8. ^ a b Niven, John. John C. Calhoun and the Price of Union, pp. 135–137 >, William W., Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816-1836, p. 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8
  9. ^ Freehling, William W., Prelude to Civil War: The Nullification Crisis in South Carolina 1816–1836, p. 143 (1965) ISBN 0-19-507681-8
  10. ^ Craven, Avery. The Coming of the Civil War, p. 65 (1942) ISBN 0-226-11894-0