Jump to content

Cube rule

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by 47.146.63.87 (talk) at 00:42, 7 January 2020 (Hatnotes). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

The cube rule or cube law is an empirical observation regarding elections under the first-past-the-post system. The rule suggests that the party getting the most votes is over-represented (and conversely, the party getting the fewest votes is under-represented). It was first formulated in a report on British elections in 1909, then extended to elections in other countries. Both in theory and in practice, the cube rule is only applicable in a two-party system. In a multi-party democracy operating under the first-past-the-post system, the cube law invariably fails, often leading to capricious results.[1]

Suppose we have two parties which receive A and B percent of the vote. According to the cube rule, the ratio of A seats-won to B seats-won should be proportional to A3/B3. So if A wins 60% and B wins 40%, the ratio of votes A/B = 60/40 = 1.5, but the ratio of seats is 603:403 = 3.375:1. That works out to a ratio of seats of 77:23. In a close election where the popular vote is A=52 and B=48, the seats break 56:44. In other words, the winner gets many extra seats. If there are three parties the ratio of seats will also be proportional to the cube of their votes.

The approximation can work well; it matched the 2002 U.S. House elections to within one seat. However, in elections for the United States House of Representatives in 1942, 1996, and 2012, the party that won a plurality of the votes actually won fewer seats in the House of Representatives.

In New Zealand, the rule predicted the distribution of seats between the two largest parties for most elections prior to election reform. From the 1940s onwards until 1993, after which the rule was irrelevant because of the introduction of mixed member proportional representation, many elections were predicted either exactly or within one seat, with most fluctuations from this in elections where there was a strong third-party showing.

However, in the UK, the cube law has operated erratically. Between 1950 and 1970, elections broadly followed the cube rule, but since 1974 the relationship has broken down, almost entirely to the benefit of the British Labour Party[citation needed]. Reasons for the recent failure of the cube law in the UK include differential turnout, the rise of the Liberal Democrats mostly at the expense of the Conservatives, tactical voting and inefficiencies in the boundary commissions.[2]

See also

References

  1. ^ Rein Taagepera, "Seats and votes: A generalization of the cube law of elections." Social Science Research 2#3 (1973): 257-275. online
  2. ^ Martin Baxter (3 September 2006). "Con-Lab Gap Analysis". Electoral Calculus. Retrieved 22 February 2015.

Further reading

  • Maloney, John; Pearson, Bernard; and Pickering, Andrew. Behind the Cube Rule: Implications of and Evidence Against a Fractal Electoral Geography (pdf) Environment and Planning A 2003 35: 1405-1404.
  • Gryski, Gerard S.; Reed, Bruce; and Elliott, Euel. “The Votes-Seats Relationship In State Legislative Elections., “American Politics Quarterly 1990 18(2): 141-157.
  • Qualter, Terence H. “Seats And Votes: An Application of the Cube Law to the Canadian Electoral System,” Canadian Journal of Political Science 1968 1(3): 336-344.
  • Rein Taagepera, ‘Reformulating the Cube Law for Proportional Representation Elections’, American Political Science Review, 80 (1986), 489–504.
  • Rein Taagepera, "Seats and votes: A generalization of the cube law of elections." Social Science Research 2#3 (1973): 257-275. online</ref>