Currency substitution
This article needs additional citations for verification. (January 2014) |
Currency substitution is the use of a foreign currency in parallel to or instead of a domestic currency.[1] The process is also known as dollarization or euroization when the foreign currency is the dollar or the euro, respectively.
Currency substitution can be full or partial. Full currency substitution can occur after a major economic crisis, such as in Ecuador, El Salvador, and Zimbabwe. Some small economies, for whom it is impractical to maintain an independent currency, use the currencies of their larger neighbours; for example, Liechtenstein uses the Swiss franc.
Partial currency substitution occurs when residents of a country choose to hold a significant share of their financial assets denominated in a foreign currency. It can also occur as a gradual conversion to full currency substitution; for example, Argentina and Peru were both in the process of converting to the U.S. dollar during the 1990s.
Origins
After the gold standard was abandoned at the outbreak of World War I and the Bretton Woods Conference following World War II, some countries sought exchange rate regimes to promote global economic stability, and hence their own prosperity. Countries usually peg their currency to a major convertible currency. "Hard pegs" are exchange rate regimes that demonstrate a stronger commitment to a fixed parity (i.e. currency boards) or relinquish control over their own currency (such as currency unions) while "soft pegs" are more flexible and floating exchange rate regimes.[2] The collapse of "soft" pegs in Southeast Asia and Latin America in the late 1990s led to currency substitution becoming a serious policy issue.[3]
A few cases of full currency substitution prior to 1999 had been the consequence of political and historical factors. In all long-standing currency substitution cases, historical and political reasons have been more influential than an evaluation of the economic effects of currency substitution.[4] Panama adopted the US dollar as legal tender after independence as the result of a constitutional ruling.[5] Ecuador and El Salvador became fully dollarized economies in 2000 and 2001 respectively, for different reasons.[4] Ecuador underwent currency substitution to deal with a widespread political and financial crisis resulting from massive loss of confidence in its political and monetary institutions. By contrast, El Salvador's official currency substitution was a result of internal debates and in a context of stable macroeconomic fundamentals and long-standing unofficial currency substitution. The eurozone adopted the euro (€) as its common currency and sole legal tender in 1999, which might be considered a variety of full-commitment regime similar to full currency substitution despite some evident differences from other currency substitutions.[6]
Measures
There are two common indicators of currency substitution. The first measure is the share of foreign currency deposits (FCD) in the domestic banking system in the broad money including FCD. The second is the share of all foreign currency deposits held by domestic residents at home and abroad in their total monetary assets.[5]
Types
Unofficial currency substitution or de facto currency substitution is the most common type of currency substitution. Unofficial currency substitution occurs when residents of a country choose to hold a significant share of their financial assets in foreign currency, even though the foreign currency is not legal tender there.[7] They hold deposits in the foreign currency because of a bad track record of the local currency, or as a hedge against inflation of the domestic currency.
Official currency substitution or full currency substitution happens when a country adopts a foreign currency as its sole legal tender, and ceases to issue the domestic currency. Another effect of a country adopting a foreign currency as its own is that the country gives up all power to vary its exchange rate. There are a small number of countries adopting a foreign currency as legal tender.
Full currency substitution has mostly occurred in Latin America, the Caribbean and the Pacific, as many countries in those regions see the United States Dollar as a stable currency compared to the national one.[8] For example, Panama underwent full currency substitution by adopting the US dollar as legal tender in 1904. This type of currency substitution is also known as de jure currency substitution.
Currency substitution can be used semiofficially (or officially bimonetary systems), where the foreign currency is legal tender alongside the domestic currency.[9]
In literature, there is a set of related definitions of currency substitution such as external liability currency substitution, domestic liability currency substitution, banking sector's liability currency substitution or deposit currency substitution, and credit dollarization. External liability currency substitution measures total external debt (private and public) denominated in foreign currencies of the economy.[9][10] Deposit currency substitution can be measured as the share of foreign currency deposits in the total deposits of the banking system, and credit currency substitution can be measured as the share of dollar credit in the total credit of the banking system.[11]
Effects
On trade and investment
One of the main advantages of adopting a strong foreign currency as sole legal tender is to reduce the transaction costs of trade among countries using the same currency.[12] There are at least two ways to infer this impact from data. The first is the significantly negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade in most cases, and the second is an association between transaction costs and the need to operate with multiple currencies.[13] Economic integration with the rest of the world becomes easier as a result of lowered transaction costs and stabler prices.[14] Rose (2000) applied the gravity model of trade and provided empirical evidence that countries sharing a common currency engage in significantly increased trade among them, and that the benefits of currency substitution for trade may be large.[15]
Countries with full currency substitution can invoke greater confidence among international investors, inducing increased investments and growth. The elimination of the currency crisis risk due to full currency substitution leads to a reduction of country risk premiums and then to lower interest rates.[14] These effects result in a higher level of investment. However, there is a positive association between currency substitution and interest rates in a dual-currency economy.[16]
On monetary and exchange rate policies
Official currency substitution helps to promote fiscal and monetary discipline and thus greater macroeconomic stability and lower inflation rates, to lower real exchange rate volatility, and possibly to deepen the financial system.[13] Firstly, currency substitution helps developing countries, providing a firm commitment to stable monetary and exchange rate policies by forcing a passive monetary policy. Adopting a strong foreign currency as legal tender will help to "eliminate the inflation-bias problem of discretionary monetary policy".[17] Secondly, official currency substitution imposes stronger financial constraint on the government by eliminating deficit financing by issuing money.[18] An empirical finding suggests that inflation has been significantly lower in economies with full currency substitution than nations with domestic currencies.[19] The expected benefit of currency substitution is the elimination of the risk of exchange rate fluctuations and a possible reduction in the country's international exposure. Currency substitution cannot eliminate the risk of an external crisis but provides steadier markets as a result of eliminating fluctuations in exchange rates.[14]
On the other hand, currency substitution leads to the loss of seigniorage revenue, the loss of monetary policy autonomy, and the loss of the exchange rate instruments. Seigniorage revenues are the profits generated when monetary authorities issue currency. When adopting a foreign currency as legal tender, a monetary authority needs to withdraw the domestic currency and give up future seigniorage revenue. The country loses the rights to its autonomous monetary and exchange rate policies, even in times of financial emergency.[14][20] For example, former chairman of the Federal Reserve Alan Greenspan has stated that the central bank considers the effects of its decisions only on the US economy.[21] In a full currency substituted economy, exchange rates are indeterminate and monetary authorities cannot devalue the currency.[22] In an economy with high currency substitution, devaluation policy is less effective in changing the real exchange rate because of significant pass-through effects to domestic prices.[14] However, the cost of losing an independent monetary policy exists when domestic monetary authorities can commit an effective counter-cyclical monetary policy, stabilizing the business cycle. This cost depends adversely on the correlation between the business cycle of the client country (the economy with currency substitution) and the business cycle of the anchor country.[12] In addition, monetary authorities in economies with currency substitution diminish the liquidity assurance to their banking system.[14][23]
On banking systems
In an economy with full currency substitution, monetary authorities cannot act as lender of last resort to commercial banks by printing money. The alternatives to lending to the bank system may include taxation and issuing government debt.[24] The loss of the lender of last resort is considered a cost of full currency substitution. This cost depends on the initial level of unofficial currency substitution before moving to a full currency substituted economy. This relation is negative because in a heavily currency substituted economy, the central bank already fears difficulties in providing liquidity assurance to the banking system.[25] However, literature points out the existence of alternative mechanisms to provide liquidity insurance to banks, such as a scheme by which the international financial community charges an insurance fee in exchange for a commitment to lend to a domestic bank.[26]
Commercial banks in countries where saving accounts and loans in foreign currency are allowed may face two types of risks:
- Currency mismatch risk: Assets and liabilities on the balance sheets may be in different denominations. This may arise if the bank converts foreign currency deposits into local currency and lends in local currency or vice versa.
- Default risk: Arises if the bank uses the foreign currency deposits to lend in foreign currency.[27]
However, currency substitution eliminates the probability of a currency crisis that negatively affects the banking system through the balance sheet channel. Currency substitution may reduce the possibility of systematic liquidity shortages and the optimal reserves in the banking system.[28] Research has shown that official currency substitution has played a significant role in improving bank liquidity and asset quality in Ecuador and El Salvador.[29]
Determinants of the currency substitution process
The dynamics of the flight from domestic money
High and unanticipated inflation rates decrease the demand for domestic money and raise the demand for alternative assets, including foreign currency and assets dominated by foreign currency. This phenomenon is called the "flight from domestic money". It results in a rapid and sizable process of currency substitution.[30] In countries with high inflation rates, the domestic currency tends to be gradually displaced by a stable currency. At the beginning of this process, the store-of-value function of the domestic currency is replaced by the foreign currency. Then, the unit-of-account function of the domestic currency is displaced when many prices are quoted in a foreign currency. A prolonged period of high inflation will induce the domestic currency to lose its function as medium of exchange when the public carries out many transactions in foreign currency.[31]: 1
Ize and Levy-Yeyati (1998) examine the determinants of deposit and credit currency substitution, concluding that currency substitution is driven by the volatility of inflation and the real exchange rate. Currency substitution increases with inflation volatility and decreases with the volatility of the real exchange rate.[32]
Institutional factors
The flight from domestic money depends on a country's institutional factors. The first factor is the level of development of the domestic financial market. An economy with a well-developed financial market can offer a set of alternative financial instruments denominated in domestic currency, reducing the role of foreign currency as an inflation hedge. The pattern of the currency substitution process also varies across countries with different foreign exchange and capital controls. In a country with strict foreign exchange regulations, the demand for foreign currency will be satisfied in the holding of foreign currency assets abroad and outside the domestic banking system. This demand often puts pressure on the parallel market of foreign currency and on the country's international reserves.[30] Evidence for this pattern is given in the absence of currency substitution during the pre-reform period in most transition economies, because of constricted controls on foreign exchange and the banking system.[31]: 13 In contrast, by increasing foreign currency reserves, a country might mitigate the shift of assets abroad and strengthen its external reserves in exchange for a currency substitution process. However, the effect of this regulation on the pattern of currency substitution depends on the public's expectations of macroeconomic stability and the sustainability of the foreign exchange regime.[30]
Anchor currencies
Australian dollar
- Kiribati (since 1943. Also uses its own coins)[33]: 17
- Nauru (since 1914)[33]: 17
- Tuvalu (since 1892. Also uses its own coins.)[33]: 17
Euro
- Andorra (formerly French franc and Spanish peseta; issued non-circulating Andorran diner coins; issues its own euro coins). Has used French and Spanish currency since 1278.[33]: 17
- Kosovo (formerly German mark and Yugoslav dinar.)
- Monaco (formerly French franc since 1865 and Monégasque franc;[33]: 17 issues its own euro coins.)
- Montenegro (formerly German mark and Yugoslav dinar.)
- North Korea (along with the Chinese yuan, United States dollar, and North Korean won)[34]
- San Marino (formerly Italian lira and Sammarinese lira; issues its own euro coins.)
- Vatican City (formerly Italian lira and Vatican lira; issues its own euro coins.)
- Zimbabwe (Alongside United States dollar, South African rand, Botswana pula, several other currencies and US dollar-denominated bond coins and bond notes of the Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS) dollar.)
Indian rupee
- Bhutan (Alongside Bhutanese ngultrum, pegged at par with the rupee)
- Nepal (Alongside the Nepali rupee, pegged at ₹0.625)
- Zimbabwe (Alongside the United States dollar, euro, Renminbi, Botswana pula, several other currencies and US dollar-denominated bond coins and bond notes of the Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS) dollar.)
New Zealand dollar
- Cook Islands (issues its own coins and some notes.)
- Niue (Also issues its own non-circulating commemorative and collector coins minted at the New Zealand Mint, pegged to the New Zealand dollar.)
- Pitcairn Islands (Also issues its own non-circulating commemorative and collector coins pegged to the New Zealand dollar.)
- Tokelau (Also issues its own non-circulating commemorative and collector coins pegged to the New Zealand dollar.)
Pound sterling
British Overseas Territories using the pound, or a local currency pegged to the pound, as their currency:
- British Indian Ocean Territory (de jure, U.S. dollar used de facto)
- Falkland Islands (alongside the Falkland Islands pound)
- Gibraltar (alongside the Gibraltar pound)
- Saint Helena, Ascension and Tristan da Cunha (Tristan da Cunha; alongside the Saint Helena pound in Saint Helena and Ascension)
- South Georgia and the South Sandwich Islands (alongside the Falkland Islands pound)
Crown Dependencies using a local issue of the pound as their currency:
Under plans published in the Sustainable Growth Commission report by the Scottish National Party, an independent Scotland would use the pound as their currency for the first 10 years of independence. This has become known as sterlingisation.
South African rand
- Eswatini (Alongside Swazi lilangeni)
- Lesotho (alongside Lesotho loti)
- Namibia (Alongside Namibian dollar)
- Zimbabwe (Alongside the United States dollar, euro, Renminbi, Botswana pula, several other currencies and US dollar-denominated bond coins and bond notes of the Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS) dollar.)
United States dollar
Countries/regions using the United States dollar exclusively
- British Virgin Islands (also issues non-circulating British Virgin Islands collector coins pegged to the U.S. dollar.)[35]
- Caribbean Netherlands (since 1 January 2011)
- Marshall Islands (has issued non-circulating collector coins of the Marshall Islands pegged to the U.S. dollar since 1986.)[36]
- Federated States of Micronesia (since 1944)[33]: 17
- Palau (since 1944; has issued non-circulating Palauan collector coins pegged to the U.S. dollar since 1992.)[33][37]
- Turks and Caicos Islands (has issued non-circulating Turks and Caicos Islands collector coins denominated in "Crowns" and pegged to the U.S. dollar.)[38]
Countries using the United States dollar alongside other currencies
- Argentina (USD is used for major purchases such as buying properties)
- Bahamas (Bahamian dollar pegged at 1:1 but USD is accepted)
- Barbados (Barbadian dollar pegged at 2:1 but USD is accepted)
- Belize (Belizean dollar pegged at 2:1 but USD is accepted)
- Bermuda (Bermudian dollar pegged at 1:1 but USD is accepted)
- Cambodia (uses the Cambodian riel for many official transactions but most businesses deal exclusively in dollars for all but the cheapest items. Change is often given in a combination of US dollars and Cambodian riel. ATMs yield US dollars rather than Cambodian riel.)[39][40]
- Costa Rica
- East Timor (uses its own coins.)
- Ecuador (since 2000. Also uses its own coins.)[33]: 1
- El Salvador (both the U.S. dollar and bitcoin are legal tender)[41]
- Haiti (uses the U.S dollar alongside its domestic currency, the gourde.)
- Honduras (used alongside the Honduran lempira)[42]
- Iraq
- Lebanon (along with the Lebanese pound)
- Liberia (exclusively used the US dollar during the early PRC period, but the National Bank of Liberia began issuing five dollar coins in 1982;[33]: 3 United States dollar still in common usage alongside the Liberian dollar.)
- North Korea (along with the Renminbi, euro, and North Korean won)[34]
- Panama (since 1904. Also uses its own coins.)[33]: 6
- Somalia (along with the Somali shilling)
- Uruguay[43]
- Venezuela (along with the Venezuelan bolívar; due to hyperinflation, USD is used for purchases such as buying electrical appliances, clothes, spare car parts and food.)[44][45]
- Vietnam (along with the Vietnamese đồng)
- Zimbabwe since 2020 (alongside South African rand, British pound, Botswana pula, Renminbi, several other currencies and US dollar-denominated bond coins and bond notes under the Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS) dollar.)
Others
- Armenian dram: Republic of Artsakh (occupied by Armenia, but claimed by Azerbaijan; also issues its own non-circulating currency for collectors.)[46][47]
- Brunei dollar: Brunei and Singapore (Alongside Singapore dollar and vice versa.)
- Danish krone: Greenland and Faroe Islands (the latter issues its own coins and some notes.)
- Hong Kong dollar: Hong Kong and Macau (Alongside Macanese pataca, pegged at $1.032)
- Egyptian pound: Palestinian territories
- New Israeli shekel: Palestinian territories
- Jordanian dinar: West Bank (Alongside the New Israeli shekel)
- Russian ruble: Abkhazia and South Ossetia (de facto independent states, but recognized as part of Georgia; issues non-circulating collector coins (Abkhazian apsar and South Ossetian zarin) pegged to the Russian ruble.)[48][49]
- Swiss franc: Liechtenstein (also issues non-circulating Liechtenstein franc collector coins.)
- Turkish lira: Turkish Republic of Northern Cyprus (de facto independent state, but recognized as part of Cyprus by all states but Turkey.)
See also
- Currency union
- Currency board
- Domestic liability dollarization
- Petrocurrency
- Bitcoin, a cryptocurrency
- World currency
References
Footnotes
- ^ New estimates of U.S. currency abroad, the domestic money supply and the unreported Economy Edgar L. Feige September 2011.
- ^ Yeyati (2003) at 1.
- ^ Rochon, Louis-Philippe (2003). Dollarization Lessons from Europe and the Americas. London and New York: Routledge. pp. 1. ISBN 9780415298780.
- ^ a b Yeyati (2003) at 3.
- ^ a b Savastano at 7.
- ^ Yeyati (2003) at 5.
- ^ Balino; Berensztein (1999). "Monetary Policy in Dollarized Economies". IMF Occasional Paper 171.
- ^ Mundell, R. A. (1961). "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas". American Economic Review. 51 (4): 657–665. JSTOR 1812792.
- ^ a b Bogetic (200). "Official Dollarization: Current Experiences and Issues". Cato Journal. 20 (2): 179–213.
- ^ Berkmen, S. Pelin; Cavallo, Eduardo (2010). "Exchange Rate Policy and Liability currency substitution: What Do the Data Reveal about Causality?". Review of International Economics. 18 (5): 781–795. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9396.2010.00890.x. S2CID 154678349.
- ^ Pinon, Marco (2008). Macroeconomic Implications of Financial currency substitution The Case of Uruguay. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund. p. 22.
- ^ a b Alesina, Alberto; Barro (2001). "Dollarization". The American Economic Review. 91 (2): 381–385. doi:10.1257/aer.91.2.381. JSTOR 2677793.
- ^ a b Yeyati (2003) at 22.
- ^ a b c d e f Berg, Andrew; Borensztein, Eduardo (2000). "The Pros and Cons of Full Dollarization". IMF Working Paper; Full Dollarization (/50). IMF. Retrieved 13 October 2011.
- ^ Rose, Andrew (2000). "One Money, One Market: the effect of common currencies on trade". Economic Policy. 15 (30): 8–0. doi:10.1111/1468-0327.00056.
- ^ Honohan, Patrick (2007). "Dollarization and Exchange Rate Fluctuations" (PDF). World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. Policy Research Working Papers (4172). doi:10.1596/1813-9450-4172. hdl:10986/7252.
- ^ Alesina, Alberto; Barro (2001). "Dollarization". The American Economic Review. 91 (2): 382. doi:10.1257/aer.91.2.381. JSTOR 2677793.
- ^ Yeyati (2003) at 23.
- ^ Edwards, Sebastian; Magendzo, I. Igal (2003). "Dollarization And Economic Performance: What Do We Really Know?". International Journal of Finance and Economics. 8 (4): 351–363. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.557.6231. doi:10.1002/ijfe.217.
- ^ Broda, Levy Yeyati, Christian, Eduardo (2003). "Endogenous deposit dollarization". Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help)CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - ^ Moreno-Bird, Juan Carlos (Fall 1999). "Dollarization in Latin America: Is it desirable?". ReVista: Harvard Review of Latin America. Archived from the original on 11 August 2011. Retrieved 27 June 2012.
- ^ John, Kareken; Wallace (1981). "On the Indeterminacy of Equilibrium Exchange Rates". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 96 (2): 207–222. doi:10.2307/1882388. JSTOR 1882388.
- ^ Yeyati, Eduardo Levy (2008). "Liquidity Insurance in a Financially Dollarized Economy". In Edwards; Garcia (eds.). Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging Markets. University of Chicago Press. pp. 185–218. ISBN 978-0-226-18495-1.
- ^ Bencivenga, Valerie; Huybens, Smith (2001). "Dollarization and the Integration of International Capital Markets: a Contribution to the Theory of Optimal Currency Areas". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 33 (2, Part 2): 548–589. doi:10.2307/2673916. JSTOR 2673916.
- ^ Broda, Christian; Yeyati (2001). "Dollarization and the Lender of Last Resort". Book: Dollarization: 100–131.
- ^ Yeyati (2003) at 31.
- ^ Kutan, Rengifo, Ozsoz, Ali, Erick, Emre. "Evaluating the Effects of Deposit Dollarization in Bank Profitability" (PDF). Fordham University Economics Department.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)[permanent dead link] - ^ Yeyati (2003) at 34.
- ^ "Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Official Dollarization and the Banking System in Ecuador and El Salvador, 2006" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 19 October 2012. Retrieved 14 September 2012.
- ^ a b c Savastano.
- ^ a b Sahay, Ratna; Vegh, Carlos (September 1995). "Dollarization in Transition Economies: Evidence and Policy Implications". IMF Working Paper No. 95/96. SSRN 883243.
- ^ Catão, Luis; Terrrones, Marco E. (August 2000). "Determinants of Dollarization: The Banking Side". IMF Working Paper No. 00/146: 5. SSRN 879949.
- ^ a b c d e f g h i j Edwards, Sebastian (May 2001). "Dollarization and Economic Performance: An Empirical Investigation". NBER Working Paper No. 8274. doi:10.3386/w8274.
- ^ a b Ruwitch, John; Park, Ju-min (2 June 2013). "Insight: North Korean economy surrenders to foreign currency invasion". Reuters. Changbai, China/Seoul. Retrieved 11 January 2017.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of the British Virgin Islands Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-09-03.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of the Marshall Islands Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-09-03.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of Palau Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-07-22.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of the Turks and Caicos Islands Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-09-03.
- ^ "Money & Cost". lonelyplanet.com. Archived from the original on 16 April 2014. Retrieved 13 December 2013.
- ^ Pilling, David; Peel, Michael (28 July 2014). "Cambodia: Wave of discontent". Financial Times. Retrieved 11 January 2017.
Dollars account for 90 per cent of money in Cambodia's banking system and almost the same proportion of cash used in everyday transactions, according to official estimates.
- ^ Kharpal, Arjun (9 June 2021). "El Salvador becomes first country to adopt bitcoin as legal tender after passing law". CNBC. Retrieved 9 June 2021.
- ^ Carter, Chris (8 May 2013). "Economy: The effect of dollarisation in Honduras". Pulsamerica. Archived from the original on 13 January 2017. Retrieved 11 January 2017.
- ^ Pinon, Marco; Gelos, Gaston (28 August 2008). "Uruguay's Monetary Policy Effective Despite Dollarization". IMF Survey Magazine. Retrieved 4 March 2012.
- ^ Zerpa, Fabiola (5 November 2019). "Venezuela Is Now More Than 50% Dollarized, Study Finds". Bloomberg. Retrieved 9 November 2019.
- ^ "Maduro says 'thank God' for dollarization in Venezuela". Reuters. 17 November 2019. Retrieved 18 November 2019.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of Artsakh Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-11-06.
- ^ Catalog of the banknotes of Artsakh Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-11-06.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of Abkhazia Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-10-14.
- ^ Catalog of the coins of South Ossetia Numista (https://en.numista.com). Retrieved on 2022-10-14.