Jump to content

Virtue signalling: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
Big changes here. I have severely edited the page, leaving in most of the previous information. I have reworded some of what was already there to avoid direct quotations from sources.
Line 1: Line 1:
'''Virtue signalling''' (or virtue signaling in [[American English]] <ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/signal|title=Definition of SIGNAL|website=www.merriam-webster.com|language=en|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref>) is the conspicuous expression of one's [[Morality|moral]] values.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.oxfordreference.com/view/10.1093/acref/9780199571123.001.0001/m_en_gb1008342|title=Virtue signalling - Oxford Reference|website=www.oxfordreference.com|language=en|doi=10.1093/acref/9780199571123.001.0001/m_en_gb1008342|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> The idea draws heavily from [[Signalling theory|signaling theory]] in [[evolutionary biology]], which posits that animals (including humans) can ascertain information about others based on traits of behaviors of said other. Virtue signaling also has roots in both [[psychology]], via [[emotional signaling]] and [[social referencing]],<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal|last=Sorce|first=James F.|last2=Emde|first2=Robert N.|last3=Campos|first3=Joseph J.|last4=Klinnert|first4=Mary D.|date=1985|title=Maternal emotional signaling: Its effect on the visual cliff behavior of 1-year-olds.|url=http://doi.apa.org/getdoi.cfm?doi=10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195|journal=Developmental Psychology|language=en|volume=21|issue=1|pages=195–200|doi=10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195|issn=1939-0599}}</ref><ref name=":5">{{Cite journal|date=1992|editor-last=Feinman|editor-first=Saul|title=Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9|doi=10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9}}</ref><ref name=":6">{{Citation|last=Bandura|first=Albert|title=Social Cognitive Theory of Social Referencing|date=1992|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9_8|work=Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy|pages=175–208|publisher=Springer US|isbn=978-1-4899-2464-3|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> and [[economics]], via [[contract theory]].<ref name=":7">{{Citation|last=Smith|first=Stephen A.|title=What is Contract Theory?|date=1993-07-29|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198765615.003.0001|work=Contract Theory|pages=3–38|publisher=Oxford University Press|isbn=978-0-19-876561-5|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> The origination of the term is credited to journalist [[James Bartholomew (journalist)|James Bartholomew]] from an article in ''[[The Spectator]]'' in 2015.<ref name=":8">{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/04/hating-the-daily-mail-is-a-substitute-for-doing-good/|title=The awful rise of ‘virtue signalling’|date=2015-04-18|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> The phrase has been criticized by a number of journalists internationally as being hypocritical,<ref name=":9">{{Cite web|url=https://www.adamsmith.org/blog/stop-saying-virtue-signalling|title=Stop saying 'virtue signalling'|website=Adam Smith Institute|language=en-GB|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref><ref name=":10">{{Cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/jan/20/virtue-signalling-putdown-passed-sell-by-date|title='Virtue-signalling' – the putdown that has passed its sell-by date {{!}} David Shariatmadari|last=Shariatmadari|first=David|date=2016-01-20|work=The Guardian|access-date=2019-11-25|language=en-GB|issn=0261-3077}}</ref> and its use continues to be a point of contention in pop culture today. Given the relatively novel nature of the term, there have been few scientific studies addressing virtue signaling, or books describing the topic sans [[Geoffrey Miller (psychologist)|Geoffrey Miller's]] 2019 collection of essays, ''Virtue Signaling: Essays on Darwinian Politics and Free Speech''.<ref name=":11">{{Cite book|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/1127937178|title=Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech|last=Miller, Geoffrey.|isbn=978-1-951555-00-9|oclc=1127937178}}</ref>
'''Virtue signalling''' is the conspicuous expression of [[Morality|moral]] values.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://en.oxforddictionaries.com/definition/virtue_signalling|title=virtue signalling – Definition of virtue signalling |website=Oxford Dictionaries – English|accessdate=26 October 2017}}</ref> Academically, the phrase relates to [[signalling theory]] and describes a subset of social behaviors that could be used to signal [[virtue]]—especially [[piety]] among the religious.<ref name="Religion">{{cite book|chapter=Religious Culture and Cooperative Prediction under Risk: Perspectives from Social Neuroscience|first1=Joseph|last1=Bulbulia|authorlink1=Joseph Bulbulia|first2=Uffe|last2=Schjoedt|title=Religion, Economy, and Cooperation|pages=37–39|year=2010|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=G4ba5zUTYaYC&pg=PA36|isbn=3110246333|via=Google Books}}</ref> Since 2015 the term has been more commonly used within groups to criticize those who are seen to value the expression of virtue over action.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/04/hating-the-daily-mail-is-a-substitute-for-doing-good/|title=The awful rise of ‘virtue signalling’|date=2015-04-18|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-06-02}}</ref>


== Academic usage ==
== Signaling Theory ==
Academically, the concept of virtue signaling stems from the signaling theories used in evolutionary biology, psychology, and economics.
[[File:Handling of serpents, a part of the ceremony at the Pentecostal Church of God. This coal camp offers none of the... - NARA - 541340.jpg|thumb|upright|right|Religious rituals such as [[snake handling]] may be explainable as costly signals.]]
===Evolutionary biology===
In [[evolutionary biology]], [[signalling theory]] is a body of [[Theory#Theories as "models"|theories as "models"]] examining [[animal communication]]. It is concerned with honest signals. For example, a peacock's tail is an honest signal of his fitness, since a less fit peacock would only be able to produce a less spectacular tail.


=== In Evolutionary Biology ===
[[Signalling_theory#Religion_as_a_costly_signal|Religion as a costly signal]], in evolutionary biology signalling theory, describes costly religious rituals such as [[circumcision]], [[fasting]] and [[abstinence]], [[snake handling]] and [[trial by ordeal]]. Signalling theorists observe that expressions of religious piety signal moral commitments. Costly signalling holds that recognition of virtue negates cost and thus "combines moral policing with virtue signalling".<ref>{{cite book |last1=Bulbulia |first1=Joseph |last2=Atkinson |first2=Quentin |last3=Gray |first3=Russell |last4=Greenhill |first4=Simon |date=2014 |title=Mind, morality and magic: Cognitive science approaches in biblical studies |chapter=Why do religious cultures evolve slowly? The cultural evolution of cooperative calling and the historical study of religions|chapter-url=https://openresearch-repository.anu.edu.au/bitstream/1885/11569/1/Bulbulia_et_al%20Why%20do%20religious%20cultures%202014.pdf |location= |publisher=Acumen Publishing |page=208}}</ref>


==== Charles Darwin and Evolution by Sexual Selection ====
===Contract theory===
[[File:Peacock with outspread plumes.JPG|thumb|The impressive plumage of peacocks is a common example of a sexually-selected trait and an [[Signalling theory|honest signal]] to potential mates.]]
In [[contract theory]], [[signalling (economics)|signalling]] is the idea that one party (termed the [[Agent (law)|agent]]) credibly conveys some information about itself to another party (the [[Principal (commercial law)|principal]]). For example, potential employees signal ability by acquiring education credentials. The principal thus believes the agent's credentials signal greater ability.<ref>{{Cite journal|doi = 10.1177/0149206310388419|title = Signaling theory: A review and assessment|journal = Journal of Management|volume = 37|issue = 1|pages = 39–67|year = 2011|last1 = Connelly|first1 = B. L.|last2 = Certo|first2 = S. T.|last3 = Ireland|first3 = R. D.|last4 = Reutzel|first4 = C. R.| url = https://www.researchgate.net/publication/254121372}}</ref> A bank with impressive architecture signals its greater financial soundness than a bank with less impressive architecture.<ref name="AdamSmithBlog">[[Sam Bowman|Bowman, S]]. (2016) ''[https://www.adamsmith.org/blog/stop-saying-virtue-signalling Stop Saying 'Virtue Signalling']'' blog post for the [[Adam Smith Institute]]</ref>
The idea of virtue signaling originates in part from the scientific study of [[Signalling theory|signaling theory]], initially conceived by [[Charles Darwin]] and his work, [[The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex|''The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex'']], published in 1871. In this book, Darwin speaks to the idea of [[evolution]] by [[sexual selection]], which posits that certain traits arise and are maintained in a species due to their ability to attract mates and therefore increase overall [[Fitness (biology)|fitness]], even when these traits would otherwise decrease an organism's relative fitness.<ref name=":02">{{Cite book|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.5962/bhl.title.110063|title=The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex /|last=Darwin|first=Charles|date=1871|publisher=John Murray,|location=London :}}</ref> Darwin suggested that a number of traits persisted in species simply due to a preference for that trait by the opposite sex.<ref name=":02" /> Common examples of the Darwinian explanation for certain traits include (but are not limited to):


* ''Bird coloration'': In many species of birds, namely the Galapagos finches studied by Darwin, males are typically bright in color. According to a strict Darwinian view, brightly colored males are preferred by females of their species over comparatively dull males. As an effect, brighter males are allotted more copulatory opportunities, which passes along to the next generation the genes denoting bright color. The preference for brightly colored males effectively removes the comparatively dull males from the mating pool, therefore resulting in an evolved population of birds with brightly colored males.<ref name=":02" />
== Pejorative usage ==
* ''Antler size'': In deer, males have antlers which typically vary in size, and those males with larger antlers are able to obtain more mates. The Darwinian view suggests that females simply prefer males with larger antlers, resulting in these males to be given a greater number of opportunities to pass along his genes. Therefore, the genes for large antlers are passed down to subsequent generations and the resulting population consists of males with large antlers and females with a preference for large antlers.<ref name=":02" />
[[File:Doing the ALS Ice Bucket Challenge (14927191426).jpg|thumb|right|A person performing the [[amyotrophic lateral sclerosis]] Ice Bucket Challenge for charity. The activity has been criticised as virtue-signalling.]]
* ''Peacock feathers'': The Darwinian view on peacock tails suggests that females prefer males with brighter and more intricate feather displays. The males with the most impressive displays would attract more females and obtain more mates, again resulting in the persistence of this trait onto subsequent generations.<ref name=":02" />
"Virtue-signalling" is also used as a [[pejorative]] term, denouncing empty acts of public commitment to unexceptional good causes such as changing Facebook profile pictures to support a cause, participating in the [[Ice Bucket Challenge]], offering [[thoughts and prayers]] after a tragedy, celebrity speeches during [[award show]]s, and politicians pandering to constituents on ideological issues.<ref name="Platitudes">{{cite news|url=https://www.bostonglobe.com/ideas/2015/12/24/virtue-signaling-and-other-inane-platitudes/YrJRcvxYMofMcCfgORUcFO/story.html|title=Virtue signaling and other inane platitudes|last=Peters|first=Mark|date=December 25, 2015|newspaper=[[Boston Globe]]|accessdate=2016-04-11}}</ref>
The term was popularised by [[James Bartholomew (journalist)|James Bartholomew]] in an article in ''[[The Spectator]]'' on 18 April 2015 to mean "public, empty gestures intended to convey socially approved attitudes without any associated risk or sacrifice".<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/04/hating-the-daily-mail-is-a-substitute-for-doing-good/|title=The awful rise of ‘virtue signalling’|date=2015-04-18|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-06-02}}</ref> {{short description|conspicuous expression of values}}
Lexicographer [[Orin Hargraves]] says that the term stems from [[social media]], which removes barriers to broadcasting sentiments. Hargraves links the term to the "[[shaming]]" category of neologisms, such as "prayer-shaming", which can have an opposite meaning to virtue signalling. [[Merriam-Webster]] editor Emily Brewster described it as an academic-sounding counterpart to "humblebrag", a term coined by [[Harris Wittels]] in 2010.<ref name="Platitudes"/>


==== Amotz Zahavi and the Handicap Principle ====
Signalling virtues such as [[environmental responsibility]] has been associated with economic decisions of consumers, such as buying "green" products and other forms of [[conspicuous conservation]].<ref name="Shariff">{{cite journal |last1=Shariff |first1=Azim |last2=Bonnefon |first2=Jean-François |last3=Rahwan |first3=Iyad |title=Psychological roadblocks to the adoption of self-driving vehicles |journal=[[Nature Human Behaviour]] |publisher=[[Springer Nature]] |series=The Multidisciplinary Nature of Machine Intelligence |date=11 September 2017 |volume=1 |issue=10 |pages=694–696 |doi=10.1038/s41562-017-0202-6 |quote=Virtue signalling is a powerful motivation for buying ethical products, but only when the ethicality is conspicuous.}}</ref><ref name="Griskevicius">{{cite journal |last1=Griskevicius |first1=Vladas |last2=Tybur |first2=Joshua M. |last3=Bram |first3=Van den Bergh |title=Going Green to Be Seen: Status, Reputation, and Conspicuous Conservation |journal=[[Journal of Personality and Social Psychology]] |date=March 2010 |volume=98 |issue=3 |pages=392–404 |doi=10.1037/a0017346 |publisher=[[American Psychological Association]]}}</ref>
Building off of Darwin's idea of sexual selection, [[Amotz Zahavi]] published a paper in 1975 entitled ''Mate Selection - the Selection for a Handicap'' in which he proposed an answer to the question of why sexually selected traits would persist in a population, given their obvious fitness costs.<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal|last=Zahavi|first=Amotz|date=1975-09|title=Mate selection—A selection for a handicap|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3|journal=Journal of Theoretical Biology|volume=53|issue=1|pages=205–214|doi=10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3|issn=0022-5193}}</ref> Zahavi suggested that the reason for the persistence of traits that seem as though they would negatively impact fitness was because of what these traits signaled to potential mates about the quality of the bearer. This became known as the [[handicap principle]].<ref name=":2">{{Cite book|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/1049806823|title=Handicap Principle : a Missing Piece of Darwin's Puzzle.|last=Zehavi, Amots.|date=1999|publisher=Oxford University Press, USA|isbn=978-0-19-802602-0|oclc=1049806823}}</ref>

In the examples above, the handicap principle provides a reason as to why these traits would persist. For example, brightly colored male birds handicap themselves by being easier to for predators to detect. However, birds that are able to produce such colors must be able to do so because of their possession of a surplus of developmental resources after all other evolutionary necessities have been met. In other words, genetically inferior males would not be able to meet all of the developmental needs and still be able to produce a bright color. In this way, brightly colored male birds are signaling their quality to females via the color handicap. The same is true for the antlers of male deer (negatively impacts mobility to escape predators) and the feathers of a peacock (negatively impacts mobility, makes it easier to be detected by predators, etc.). In all examples, the handicap provides an honest signal to mates regarding the genetic quality of the trait-bearer, which makes the traits highly attractive in the [[Mating|mating market]].<ref name=":1" /><ref name=":2" /> This animal-centric view of signaling theory has been accepted as applicable to human behavior, though signaling theorists have been simultaneously criticized for being too reliant on the handicap principle as a sole explanation for reliable honest signals in human linguistic communication.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=SCOTT-PHILLIPS|first=THOMAS C.|date=2008-02|title=ON THE CORRECT APPLICATION OF ANIMAL SIGNALLING THEORY TO HUMAN COMMUNICATION|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/9789812776129_0035|journal=The Evolution of Language|publisher=WORLD SCIENTIFIC|doi=10.1142/9789812776129_0035|isbn=978-981-277-611-2}}</ref>

=== In Psychology ===
Signaling has myriad applications in psychological fields, spanning across [[Social psychology|social]], [[Cognitive psychology|cognitive]], [[Evolutionary psychology|evolutionary]], and [[Developmental psychology|developmental]] [[psychology]]. Psychologists in these fields primarily study signaling as it pertains to emotion and how emotional signaling affects social relations. Numerous studies have been conducted specifically on infants and the relation between signaling theory and social referencing.

==== Emotional Signaling and Social Referencing ====
[[File:NIH visual cliff experiment.png|thumb|A picture of a mother and her child using the [[visual cliff]] apparatus.]]
Studies of [[Child development|infant development]] have shown that infants use social referencing via maternal signaling to obtain information in the presence of situational ambiguity. One study used the [[Visual cliff|visual cliff experimental paradigm]] to assess an infant's ability to perceive information from its mother.<ref name=":32">{{Cite journal|last=Sorce|first=James F.|last2=Emde|first2=Robert N.|last3=Campos|first3=Joseph J.|last4=Klinnert|first4=Mary D.|date=1985|title=Maternal emotional signaling: Its effect on the visual cliff behavior of 1-year-olds.|url=http://doi.apa.org/getdoi.cfm?doi=10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195|journal=Developmental Psychology|language=en|volume=21|issue=1|pages=195–200|doi=10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195|issn=1939-0599}}</ref> In the visual cliff design, infants are placed on a lifted, crib-like platform in which a portion of the floor is comprised of plexiglass, allowing the infant to see what it perceives to be a significant drop to the floor. This effectively creates the illusion of a "visual cliff."<ref>{{Cite journal|date=1960|title=The Visual Cliff Study: Eleanor J. Gibson and Richard D. Walk reels of animals on the Visual Cliff 7|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.4135/9781473982055|doi=10.4135/9781473982055}}</ref> Originally created to test depth perception in developing infants, the visual cliff has been used in more recent years in conjunction with emotional signaling; children see their mothers expressing either positive (happy) or negative (sad) [[emotion]], which subsequently affects the infant's willingness to take the risk by crawling over the plexiglass toward its parent.<ref name=":32" /> Studies such as this one suggest that emotional signaling is a useful tool in social learning and social decision-making from an early age.<ref name=":52">{{Cite journal|date=1992|editor-last=Feinman|editor-first=Saul|title=Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9|doi=10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9}}</ref><ref name=":62">{{Citation|last=Bandura|first=Albert|title=Social Cognitive Theory of Social Referencing|date=1992|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9_8|work=Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy|pages=175–208|publisher=Springer US|isbn=978-1-4899-2464-3|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref>

This is further evidenced through the proposed evolutionary purpose of external emotional indicators such as tears. One study suggests that tears exist as an biologically evolved signal of sadness.<ref name=":4">{{Cite journal|last=Hasson|first=Oren|date=2009-07|title=Emotional Tears as Biological Signals|url=http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/147470490900700302|journal=Evolutionary Psychology|language=en|volume=7|issue=3|pages=147470490900700|doi=10.1177/147470490900700302|issn=1474-7049}}</ref> This signaling conveys to others information regarding one's internal emotional state that might otherwise be difficult to ascertain. In this way, crying could have evolved as an honest indicator and external expression of sadness.<ref name=":4" /> This argument speaks to the strength of signaling as a social tool, allowing humans to silently and honestly convey information to others.

Additionally, at least one evolutionary psychological study has suggested that signaling can potentially help to explain risk-taking behavior. A 2009 paper found a highly sex-specific tendency for men to disproportionately partake in risky behaviors when they knew that such behaviors were being observed by women.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Baker|first=Michael D.|last2=Maner|first2=Jon K.|date=2009-09-01|title=Male risk-taking as a context-sensitive signaling device|url=http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S002210310900136X|journal=Journal of Experimental Social Psychology|volume=45|issue=5|pages=1136–1139|doi=10.1016/j.jesp.2009.06.006|issn=0022-1031}}</ref> This suggests that perhaps risk-taking could be an evolved behavior, and signals specific characteristics of the risky male to potential female suitors.

=== In Economics ===

==== Contract Theory ====
[[Michael Spence]] is credited with originating [[Signalling (economics)|signaling]] in the field of [[economics]] via [[contract theory]]. Contract theory suggests that economic actors (sometimes referred to as [[Agent (economics)|agents]]) tend to enter into some sort of contractual obligation or mutual agreement when confronted with asymmetrical information.<ref name=":72">{{Citation|last=Smith|first=Stephen A.|title=What is Contract Theory?|date=1993-07-29|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198765615.003.0001|work=Contract Theory|pages=3–38|publisher=Oxford University Press|isbn=978-0-19-876561-5|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> An actor can be a business, an individual, a corporate entity, or any number of parties which influence the economy.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://financial-dictionary.thefreedictionary.com/Economic+Actors|title=Economic Actors|website=TheFreeDictionary.com|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> As it applies to contract theory, signaling is used by one actor to surmise information about another actor when asymmetrical information is available between the two parties. Some examples are:

* An individual searching for a job may not know much information about the companies to which he or she is applying, nor does the company likely know information about the applicant. To remedy this asymmetrical information, an applicant might provide a resumé or CV, which serves as a signal of the applicant's quality as an employee. This is an example of the [[Signalling (economics)|job-market-signaling]] model provided by Michael Spence in the 1970s.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Spence|first=Michael|date=1973-08|title=Job Market Signaling|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1882010|journal=The Quarterly Journal of Economics|volume=87|issue=3|pages=355|doi=10.2307/1882010|issn=0033-5533}}</ref>
* Similarly, a bank with impressive architecture might use this as a signal of its comparatively superior financial soundness than a bank with less impressive architecture.<ref name=":92">{{Cite web|url=https://www.adamsmith.org/blog/stop-saying-virtue-signalling|title=Stop saying 'virtue signalling'|website=Adam Smith Institute|language=en-GB|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>

In either scenario, agents are signaling something to other agents that allows the latter to fill in the knowledge gaps left by the existence of asymmetrical information.

== Origin of Virtue Signaling ==
British journalist [[James Bartholomew (journalist)|James Bartholomew]] is often credited with originating the term "virtue signalling" in an article in ''[[The Spectator]]'' in 2015.<ref name=":82">{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/04/hating-the-daily-mail-is-a-substitute-for-doing-good/|title=The awful rise of ‘virtue signalling’|date=2015-04-18|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> The blog LessWrong used the phrase in 2013,<ref name=":12">{{Cite web|url=https://www.thesun.co.uk/living/2701968/virtue-signalling-meaning-origin-examples/|title=What is virtue signalling? Meaning, origin and examples – here’s all you need to know|date=2017-03-08|website=The Sun|language=en-gb|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref> but Bartholomew claimed credit for the creation of the phrase in later articles<ref name=":13">{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/10/i-invented-virtue-signalling-now-its-taking-over-the-world/|title=I invented ‘virtue signalling’. Now it’s taking over the world|date=2015-10-10|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.cis.org.au/commentary/articles/despite-virtue-signalling-words-tend-to-fail-the-right/|title=Despite ‘virtue signalling’, words tend to fail the Right|website=The Centre for Independent Studies|language=en-AU|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>, mentioning that its popularity was likely due to a prior lack of terminology referring to the act.<ref name=":13" /> As he suggested, the concept of virtue signaling had been around for much longer than the term describing such acts. Indeed, in his 2019 book, ''Virtue Signaling: Essays on Darwinian Politics and Free Speech'', evolutionary psychologist and [[Freedom of speech|free-speech]] advocate [[Geoffrey Miller (psychologist)|Geoffrey Miller]] echoes that he had witnessed the act of virtue signaling for years, but did not quite have the right phrase to describe it.<ref name=":112">{{Cite book|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/1127937178|title=Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech|last=Miller, Geoffrey.|isbn=978-1-951555-00-9|oclc=1127937178}}</ref>

Lexicographer [[Orin Hargraves]] argues that the term stems from [[social media]], which removes the barriers to broadcasting one's sentiments. Hargraves links the term to the "shaming" category of [[Neologism|neologisms]], such as "prayer-shaming" or "fat-shaming," which in themselves can be a form of virtue signaling; one's outward distaste for another's prayer, for example, signals the former's moral values regarding the act. Bartholomew also addressed the significance of social media in virtue signaling, pointing out that the short character limits on [[Twitter]] make it much easier to virtue signal than to formulate an argument.<ref name=":82" />

[[Merriam-Webster]] editor Emily Brewster describes virtue signaling as an academic-sounding counterpart to the term "[[Harris Wittels|humblebrag]]," a term coined by [[Harris Wittels]] in 2010.<ref name=":14">{{Cite web|url=https://www.bostonglobe.com/ideas/2015/12/24/virtue-signaling-and-other-inane-platitudes/YrJRcvxYMofMcCfgORUcFO/story.html|title=Virtue signaling and other inane platitudes - The Boston Globe|website=BostonGlobe.com|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>

== Usage ==
[[File:Doing the ALS Ice Bucket Challenge (14927191426).jpg|thumb|right|A person performing the [[amyotrophic lateral sclerosis]] Ice Bucket Challenge for charity. The activity has been criticised as virtue-signalling.|287x287px]]
Virtue signaling rose in popularity as a pejorative term, denouncing empty acts of public commitment to unexceptional good causes. The term is characterized by the signaler's desire to show support for a cause without actually acting to support the cause in question. An important characteristic of virtue signaling is that there is little to no cost associated with the act; simple public vocalization in support of a cause has no cost to the signaler. In Bartholomew's original article, he describes virtue signaling as a public act with very little associated cost that is intended to inform others of one's socially acceptable alignment on an issue.<ref name=":83">{{Cite web|url=https://www.spectator.co.uk/2015/04/hating-the-daily-mail-is-a-substitute-for-doing-good/|title=The awful rise of ‘virtue signalling’|date=2015-04-18|website=The Spectator|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-24}}</ref> [[Geoffrey Miller (psychologist)|Geoffrey Miller]] describes virtue signaling as an innate act, and something that all humans do and cannot avoid.<ref name=":113">{{Cite book|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/1127937178|title=Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech|last=Miller, Geoffrey.|isbn=978-1-951555-00-9|oclc=1127937178}}</ref> Some examples of common virtue signaling include:

* Changing one's [[Facebook]] profile picture to support a cause<ref name=":142">{{Cite web|url=https://www.bostonglobe.com/ideas/2015/12/24/virtue-signaling-and-other-inane-platitudes/YrJRcvxYMofMcCfgORUcFO/story.html|title=Virtue signaling and other inane platitudes - The Boston Globe|website=BostonGlobe.com|language=en-US|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>
* Participating in the [[Ice Bucket Challenge]] for [[amyotrophic lateral sclerosis]]<ref name=":142" />
* Offering [[thoughts and prayers]] after a tragedy<ref name=":142" />
* Celebrity speeches during award shows or public gatherings,<ref name=":142" /> such as comedian [[Michelle Wolf]]'s comment during her speech at the 2018 [[White House Correspondents' Association|White House Correspondent's Dinner]] referring to the state of the non-potable water in [[Flint, Michigan]] at the time.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.cnn.com/2018/04/30/us/flint-water-correspondents-dinner-michelle-wolf-trnd/index.html|title=The most damning line from the Correspondents' Dinner? 'Flint still doesn't have clean water'|last=CNN|first=Eric Levenson|website=CNN|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>
* Politicians pandering to constituents on ideological issues,<ref name=":142" /> such as promising a higher minimum wage to signal support for the lower classes<ref name=":83" />
* Voicing hatred for large vehicles to show [[Environmentalism|environmental consciousness]]<ref name=":83" />
* Wishing someone a "great" day to indicate superior kindness compared to those who wish a "good" day<ref name=":83" />
* Advocating for women's organizations to advertise a respect and love for women<ref name=":83" />
* Denouncing upper-class consumer goods or news publications to show support for the less fortunate<ref name=":83" />
* Publicly donating to charity to appear virtuous<ref name=":122">{{Cite web|url=https://www.thesun.co.uk/living/2701968/virtue-signalling-meaning-origin-examples/|title=What is virtue signalling? Meaning, origin and examples – here’s all you need to know|date=2017-03-08|website=The Sun|language=en-gb|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>

[[File:Snake-handling-lejunior-pentecostal-ky2.gif|thumb|234x234px|Religious [[Snake handling in religion|snake handling]] is seen by some to be a form of virtue signaling.]]
Some advocates of signaling theory use virtue signaling to describe the persistence or occurrence of various costly religious practices such as [[circumcision]], [[fasting]], [[Snake handling in religion|snake handling]], and [[trial by ordeal]]. This idea is that the participation in an act with a religious purpose serves as a way to signal one's dedication to the beliefs held by that religion, thereby signaling personal morality to onlookers.<ref>{{Citation|last=Bulbulia|first=Joseph|title=Religious Culture and Cooperative Prediction under Risk: Perspectives from Social Neuroscience|date=2010-07-16|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/9783110246339.35|work=Religion, Economy, and Cooperation|pages=35–60|publisher=DE GRUYTER|isbn=978-3-11-024632-2|access-date=2019-11-25|last2=Schjoedt|first2=Uffe}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|last=Bulbulia|first=Joseph|title=Why do religious cultures evolve slowly? The cultural evolution of cooperative calling and the historical study of religions|date=2014-04|url=https://openresearch-repository.anu.edu.au/handle/1885/11569|work=http://universitypublishingonline.org/acumen/chapter.jsf?bid=CBO9781844657346&cid=CBO9781844657346A021|publisher=Acumen Publishing|language=en|isbn=978-1-84465-734-6|access-date=2019-11-25|last2=Atkinson|first2=Quentin|last3=Gray|first3=Russell|last4=Greenhill|first4=Simon}}</ref>


=== Criticism ===
=== Criticism ===
Jane Coaston of ''[[The New York Times]]'' notes that in using the term "virtue signalling" one is "trying to signal something about their own values: that they are pragmatic, appropriately cynical, in touch with the painful facts of everyday life".<ref>{{Cite news|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2017/08/08/magazine/virtue-signaling-isnt-the-problem-not-believing-one-another-is.html|title=‘Virtue Signaling’ Isn’t the Problem. Not Believing One Another Is|last=Coaston|first=Jane|date=2017-08-08|work=The New York Times|access-date=2019-01-17|language=en-US|issn=0362-4331}}</ref> In ''[[The Guardian]]'', David Shariatmadari argues that this makes it "indistinguishable from the thing it was designed to call out" adding that it is "smug posturing from a position of self-appointed authority."<ref name="Sell-By">{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/jan/20/virtue-signalling-putdown-passed-sell-by-date|title=Virtue-signalling&nbsp;– the putdown that has passed its sell-by date|last=Shariatmadari|first=David|date=January 20, 2016|newspaper=[[The Guardian]]|accessdate=2016-04-11}}</ref> Neoliberal political theorist and economist [[Sam Bowman]], criticized the term claiming that "saying virtue signalling is hypocritical. It’s often used to try to show that the accuser is above virtue signalling and that their own arguments really are sincere."<ref name="AdamSmithBlog" />
Since the conception of the phrase, virtue signaling has received mixed reviews regarding its validity. In an opinion piece in ''[[The New York Times]]'', psychologists Jillian Jordan and [[David G. Rand|David Rand]] argue that virtue signaling (i.e. feigned outrage) is separable from true outrage towards a particular belief, but that in most cases individuals who are virtue signaling are in fact simultaneously experiencing true outrage.<ref>{{Cite news|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2019/03/30/opinion/sunday/virtue-signaling.html|title=Opinion {{!}} Are You ‘Virtue Signaling’?|last=Jordan|first=Jillian|date=2019-03-30|work=The New York Times|access-date=2019-11-25|last2=Rand|first2=David|language=en-US|issn=0362-4331}}</ref> In an article from ''[[The Guardian]]'', David Shariatmadari argues that the typicality of virtue signaling to show-off one's own values makes it no different than the acts that it was supposed to abhor. That is, virtue signaling is designed to call out individuals on their lack of action, but the very act of doing so is an act of virtue signaling in itself. He addresses the recognition of one's virtue signaling as "smug" and points out that it comes from individuals with a false sense of power or superiority.<ref name=":102">{{Cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/jan/20/virtue-signalling-putdown-passed-sell-by-date|title='Virtue-signalling' – the putdown that has passed its sell-by date {{!}} David Shariatmadari|last=Shariatmadari|first=David|date=2016-01-20|work=The Guardian|access-date=2019-11-25|language=en-GB|issn=0261-3077}}</ref> In a similar vein, political theorist and economist [[Sam Bowman]] argued that the term is hypocritical in that calling out another individual's actions as virtue signaling is simply another form of virtue signaling, executed to heighten the perceived status of the accuser.<ref name=":93">{{Cite web|url=https://www.adamsmith.org/blog/stop-saying-virtue-signalling|title=Stop saying 'virtue signalling'|website=Adam Smith Institute|language=en-GB|access-date=2019-11-25}}</ref>


[[Adam Smith Institute]] Executive Director [[Sam Bowman]] opined that the meaning of the term popularised by James Bartholomew misuses the concept of signalling and encourages lazy thinking.<ref name="AdamSmithBlog" /> In ''[[The Guardian]]'', [[Zoe Williams]] suggested the phrase was the "sequel insult to [[champagne socialist]]"<ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/apr/10/labour-heartland-doesnt-exist-voters|last1=Williams|first1=Zoe|authorlink1=Zoe Williams|title=Forget about Labour's heartland&nbsp;– it doesn’t exist|date=April 10, 2016|newspaper=[[The Guardian]]|accessdate=2016-04-11}}</ref> while fellow ''Guardian'' writer David Shariatmadari says that while the term serves a purpose, its overuse as an ''[[ad hominem]]'' attack during political debate has rendered it a meaningless political [[buzzword]].<ref name="Sell-By"/> Consequently, the antonym "vice signalling" has emerged to refer to blatant amorality.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.ft.com/content/cf4d3d5c-7129-11e9-bf5c-6eeb837566c5|title=Once you’re accused of virtue-signalling, you can’t do anything right|author=Robert Shrimsley|date=2019-05-10|publisher=Financial Times}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://blogs.spectator.co.uk/2018/05/the-tories-are-the-masters-of-vice-signalling/|title=The Tories are the masters of ‘vice signalling’|author=[[Nick Cohen]]|date=2018-05-25|publisher=Spectator}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.middleeasteye.net/news/world-community-needs-do-more-about-saudi-abuses-us-lawmakers-say|title=Saudi activists and US lawmakers join call for end to 'sadistic' abuses by MBS|author=Ali Harb|date=2019-05-23|publisher=Middle East Eye}}</ref>
[[Adam Smith Institute]] Executive Director [[Sam Bowman]] opined that the meaning of the term popularised by James Bartholomew misuses the concept of signalling and encourages lazy thinking.<ref name="AdamSmithBlog">[[Sam Bowman|Bowman, S]]. (2016) ''[https://www.adamsmith.org/blog/stop-saying-virtue-signalling Stop Saying 'Virtue Signalling']'' blog post for the [[Adam Smith Institute]]</ref> In ''[[The Guardian]]'', [[Zoe Williams]] suggested the phrase was the "sequel insult to [[champagne socialist]]"<ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/apr/10/labour-heartland-doesnt-exist-voters|last1=Williams|first1=Zoe|authorlink1=Zoe Williams|title=Forget about Labour's heartland&nbsp;– it doesn’t exist|date=April 10, 2016|newspaper=[[The Guardian]]|accessdate=2016-04-11}}</ref> while fellow ''Guardian'' writer David Shariatmadari says that while the term serves a purpose, its overuse as an ''[[ad hominem]]'' attack during political debate has rendered it a meaningless political [[buzzword]].<ref name="Sell-By">{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2016/jan/20/virtue-signalling-putdown-passed-sell-by-date|title=Virtue-signalling&nbsp;– the putdown that has passed its sell-by date|last=Shariatmadari|first=David|date=January 20, 2016|newspaper=[[The Guardian]]|accessdate=2016-04-11}}</ref> Consequently, the antonym "vice signalling" has emerged to refer to blatant amorality.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.ft.com/content/cf4d3d5c-7129-11e9-bf5c-6eeb837566c5|title=Once you’re accused of virtue-signalling, you can’t do anything right|author=Robert Shrimsley|date=2019-05-10|publisher=Financial Times}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://blogs.spectator.co.uk/2018/05/the-tories-are-the-masters-of-vice-signalling/|title=The Tories are the masters of ‘vice signalling’|author=[[Nick Cohen]]|date=2018-05-25|publisher=Spectator}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.middleeasteye.net/news/world-community-needs-do-more-about-saudi-abuses-us-lawmakers-say|title=Saudi activists and US lawmakers join call for end to 'sadistic' abuses by MBS|author=Ali Harb|date=2019-05-23|publisher=Middle East Eye}}</ref>


== See also ==
== See also ==

Revision as of 07:58, 25 November 2019

Virtue signalling (or virtue signaling in American English [1]) is the conspicuous expression of one's moral values.[2] The idea draws heavily from signaling theory in evolutionary biology, which posits that animals (including humans) can ascertain information about others based on traits of behaviors of said other. Virtue signaling also has roots in both psychology, via emotional signaling and social referencing,[3][4][5] and economics, via contract theory.[6] The origination of the term is credited to journalist James Bartholomew from an article in The Spectator in 2015.[7] The phrase has been criticized by a number of journalists internationally as being hypocritical,[8][9] and its use continues to be a point of contention in pop culture today. Given the relatively novel nature of the term, there have been few scientific studies addressing virtue signaling, or books describing the topic sans Geoffrey Miller's 2019 collection of essays, Virtue Signaling: Essays on Darwinian Politics and Free Speech.[10]

Signaling Theory

Academically, the concept of virtue signaling stems from the signaling theories used in evolutionary biology, psychology, and economics.

In Evolutionary Biology

Charles Darwin and Evolution by Sexual Selection

The impressive plumage of peacocks is a common example of a sexually-selected trait and an honest signal to potential mates.

The idea of virtue signaling originates in part from the scientific study of signaling theory, initially conceived by Charles Darwin and his work, The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex, published in 1871. In this book, Darwin speaks to the idea of evolution by sexual selection, which posits that certain traits arise and are maintained in a species due to their ability to attract mates and therefore increase overall fitness, even when these traits would otherwise decrease an organism's relative fitness.[11] Darwin suggested that a number of traits persisted in species simply due to a preference for that trait by the opposite sex.[11] Common examples of the Darwinian explanation for certain traits include (but are not limited to):

  • Bird coloration: In many species of birds, namely the Galapagos finches studied by Darwin, males are typically bright in color. According to a strict Darwinian view, brightly colored males are preferred by females of their species over comparatively dull males. As an effect, brighter males are allotted more copulatory opportunities, which passes along to the next generation the genes denoting bright color. The preference for brightly colored males effectively removes the comparatively dull males from the mating pool, therefore resulting in an evolved population of birds with brightly colored males.[11]
  • Antler size: In deer, males have antlers which typically vary in size, and those males with larger antlers are able to obtain more mates. The Darwinian view suggests that females simply prefer males with larger antlers, resulting in these males to be given a greater number of opportunities to pass along his genes. Therefore, the genes for large antlers are passed down to subsequent generations and the resulting population consists of males with large antlers and females with a preference for large antlers.[11]
  • Peacock feathers: The Darwinian view on peacock tails suggests that females prefer males with brighter and more intricate feather displays. The males with the most impressive displays would attract more females and obtain more mates, again resulting in the persistence of this trait onto subsequent generations.[11]

Amotz Zahavi and the Handicap Principle

Building off of Darwin's idea of sexual selection, Amotz Zahavi published a paper in 1975 entitled Mate Selection - the Selection for a Handicap in which he proposed an answer to the question of why sexually selected traits would persist in a population, given their obvious fitness costs.[12] Zahavi suggested that the reason for the persistence of traits that seem as though they would negatively impact fitness was because of what these traits signaled to potential mates about the quality of the bearer. This became known as the handicap principle.[13]

In the examples above, the handicap principle provides a reason as to why these traits would persist. For example, brightly colored male birds handicap themselves by being easier to for predators to detect. However, birds that are able to produce such colors must be able to do so because of their possession of a surplus of developmental resources after all other evolutionary necessities have been met. In other words, genetically inferior males would not be able to meet all of the developmental needs and still be able to produce a bright color. In this way, brightly colored male birds are signaling their quality to females via the color handicap. The same is true for the antlers of male deer (negatively impacts mobility to escape predators) and the feathers of a peacock (negatively impacts mobility, makes it easier to be detected by predators, etc.). In all examples, the handicap provides an honest signal to mates regarding the genetic quality of the trait-bearer, which makes the traits highly attractive in the mating market.[12][13] This animal-centric view of signaling theory has been accepted as applicable to human behavior, though signaling theorists have been simultaneously criticized for being too reliant on the handicap principle as a sole explanation for reliable honest signals in human linguistic communication.[14]

In Psychology

Signaling has myriad applications in psychological fields, spanning across social, cognitive, evolutionary, and developmental psychology. Psychologists in these fields primarily study signaling as it pertains to emotion and how emotional signaling affects social relations. Numerous studies have been conducted specifically on infants and the relation between signaling theory and social referencing.

Emotional Signaling and Social Referencing

A picture of a mother and her child using the visual cliff apparatus.

Studies of infant development have shown that infants use social referencing via maternal signaling to obtain information in the presence of situational ambiguity. One study used the visual cliff experimental paradigm to assess an infant's ability to perceive information from its mother.[15] In the visual cliff design, infants are placed on a lifted, crib-like platform in which a portion of the floor is comprised of plexiglass, allowing the infant to see what it perceives to be a significant drop to the floor. This effectively creates the illusion of a "visual cliff."[16] Originally created to test depth perception in developing infants, the visual cliff has been used in more recent years in conjunction with emotional signaling; children see their mothers expressing either positive (happy) or negative (sad) emotion, which subsequently affects the infant's willingness to take the risk by crawling over the plexiglass toward its parent.[15] Studies such as this one suggest that emotional signaling is a useful tool in social learning and social decision-making from an early age.[17][18]

This is further evidenced through the proposed evolutionary purpose of external emotional indicators such as tears. One study suggests that tears exist as an biologically evolved signal of sadness.[19] This signaling conveys to others information regarding one's internal emotional state that might otherwise be difficult to ascertain. In this way, crying could have evolved as an honest indicator and external expression of sadness.[19] This argument speaks to the strength of signaling as a social tool, allowing humans to silently and honestly convey information to others.

Additionally, at least one evolutionary psychological study has suggested that signaling can potentially help to explain risk-taking behavior. A 2009 paper found a highly sex-specific tendency for men to disproportionately partake in risky behaviors when they knew that such behaviors were being observed by women.[20] This suggests that perhaps risk-taking could be an evolved behavior, and signals specific characteristics of the risky male to potential female suitors.

In Economics

Contract Theory

Michael Spence is credited with originating signaling in the field of economics via contract theory. Contract theory suggests that economic actors (sometimes referred to as agents) tend to enter into some sort of contractual obligation or mutual agreement when confronted with asymmetrical information.[21] An actor can be a business, an individual, a corporate entity, or any number of parties which influence the economy.[22] As it applies to contract theory, signaling is used by one actor to surmise information about another actor when asymmetrical information is available between the two parties. Some examples are:

  • An individual searching for a job may not know much information about the companies to which he or she is applying, nor does the company likely know information about the applicant. To remedy this asymmetrical information, an applicant might provide a resumé or CV, which serves as a signal of the applicant's quality as an employee. This is an example of the job-market-signaling model provided by Michael Spence in the 1970s.[23]
  • Similarly, a bank with impressive architecture might use this as a signal of its comparatively superior financial soundness than a bank with less impressive architecture.[24]

In either scenario, agents are signaling something to other agents that allows the latter to fill in the knowledge gaps left by the existence of asymmetrical information.

Origin of Virtue Signaling

British journalist James Bartholomew is often credited with originating the term "virtue signalling" in an article in The Spectator in 2015.[25] The blog LessWrong used the phrase in 2013,[26] but Bartholomew claimed credit for the creation of the phrase in later articles[27][28], mentioning that its popularity was likely due to a prior lack of terminology referring to the act.[27] As he suggested, the concept of virtue signaling had been around for much longer than the term describing such acts. Indeed, in his 2019 book, Virtue Signaling: Essays on Darwinian Politics and Free Speech, evolutionary psychologist and free-speech advocate Geoffrey Miller echoes that he had witnessed the act of virtue signaling for years, but did not quite have the right phrase to describe it.[29]

Lexicographer Orin Hargraves argues that the term stems from social media, which removes the barriers to broadcasting one's sentiments. Hargraves links the term to the "shaming" category of neologisms, such as "prayer-shaming" or "fat-shaming," which in themselves can be a form of virtue signaling; one's outward distaste for another's prayer, for example, signals the former's moral values regarding the act. Bartholomew also addressed the significance of social media in virtue signaling, pointing out that the short character limits on Twitter make it much easier to virtue signal than to formulate an argument.[25]

Merriam-Webster editor Emily Brewster describes virtue signaling as an academic-sounding counterpart to the term "humblebrag," a term coined by Harris Wittels in 2010.[30]

Usage

A person performing the amyotrophic lateral sclerosis Ice Bucket Challenge for charity. The activity has been criticised as virtue-signalling.

Virtue signaling rose in popularity as a pejorative term, denouncing empty acts of public commitment to unexceptional good causes. The term is characterized by the signaler's desire to show support for a cause without actually acting to support the cause in question. An important characteristic of virtue signaling is that there is little to no cost associated with the act; simple public vocalization in support of a cause has no cost to the signaler. In Bartholomew's original article, he describes virtue signaling as a public act with very little associated cost that is intended to inform others of one's socially acceptable alignment on an issue.[31] Geoffrey Miller describes virtue signaling as an innate act, and something that all humans do and cannot avoid.[32] Some examples of common virtue signaling include:

Religious snake handling is seen by some to be a form of virtue signaling.

Some advocates of signaling theory use virtue signaling to describe the persistence or occurrence of various costly religious practices such as circumcision, fasting, snake handling, and trial by ordeal. This idea is that the participation in an act with a religious purpose serves as a way to signal one's dedication to the beliefs held by that religion, thereby signaling personal morality to onlookers.[36][37]

Criticism

Since the conception of the phrase, virtue signaling has received mixed reviews regarding its validity. In an opinion piece in The New York Times, psychologists Jillian Jordan and David Rand argue that virtue signaling (i.e. feigned outrage) is separable from true outrage towards a particular belief, but that in most cases individuals who are virtue signaling are in fact simultaneously experiencing true outrage.[38] In an article from The Guardian, David Shariatmadari argues that the typicality of virtue signaling to show-off one's own values makes it no different than the acts that it was supposed to abhor. That is, virtue signaling is designed to call out individuals on their lack of action, but the very act of doing so is an act of virtue signaling in itself. He addresses the recognition of one's virtue signaling as "smug" and points out that it comes from individuals with a false sense of power or superiority.[39] In a similar vein, political theorist and economist Sam Bowman argued that the term is hypocritical in that calling out another individual's actions as virtue signaling is simply another form of virtue signaling, executed to heighten the perceived status of the accuser.[40]

Adam Smith Institute Executive Director Sam Bowman opined that the meaning of the term popularised by James Bartholomew misuses the concept of signalling and encourages lazy thinking.[41] In The Guardian, Zoe Williams suggested the phrase was the "sequel insult to champagne socialist"[42] while fellow Guardian writer David Shariatmadari says that while the term serves a purpose, its overuse as an ad hominem attack during political debate has rendered it a meaningless political buzzword.[43] Consequently, the antonym "vice signalling" has emerged to refer to blatant amorality.[44][45][46]

See also

References

  1. ^ "Definition of SIGNAL". www.merriam-webster.com. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  2. ^ "Virtue signalling - Oxford Reference". www.oxfordreference.com. doi:10.1093/acref/9780199571123.001.0001/m_en_gb1008342. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  3. ^ Sorce, James F.; Emde, Robert N.; Campos, Joseph J.; Klinnert, Mary D. (1985). "Maternal emotional signaling: Its effect on the visual cliff behavior of 1-year-olds". Developmental Psychology. 21 (1): 195–200. doi:10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195. ISSN 1939-0599.
  4. ^ Feinman, Saul, ed. (1992). "Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy". doi:10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  5. ^ Bandura, Albert (1992), "Social Cognitive Theory of Social Referencing", Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy, Springer US, pp. 175–208, ISBN 978-1-4899-2464-3, retrieved 2019-11-24
  6. ^ Smith, Stephen A. (1993-07-29), "What is Contract Theory?", Contract Theory, Oxford University Press, pp. 3–38, ISBN 978-0-19-876561-5, retrieved 2019-11-24
  7. ^ "The awful rise of 'virtue signalling'". The Spectator. 2015-04-18. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  8. ^ "Stop saying 'virtue signalling'". Adam Smith Institute. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  9. ^ Shariatmadari, David (2016-01-20). "'Virtue-signalling' – the putdown that has passed its sell-by date | David Shariatmadari". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  10. ^ Miller, Geoffrey. Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech. ISBN 978-1-951555-00-9. OCLC 1127937178.
  11. ^ a b c d e Darwin, Charles (1871). The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex /. London :: John Murray,.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: extra punctuation (link)
  12. ^ a b Zahavi, Amotz (1975-09). "Mate selection—A selection for a handicap". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 53 (1): 205–214. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3. ISSN 0022-5193. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  13. ^ a b Zehavi, Amots. (1999). Handicap Principle : a Missing Piece of Darwin's Puzzle. Oxford University Press, USA. ISBN 978-0-19-802602-0. OCLC 1049806823.
  14. ^ SCOTT-PHILLIPS, THOMAS C. (2008-02). "ON THE CORRECT APPLICATION OF ANIMAL SIGNALLING THEORY TO HUMAN COMMUNICATION". The Evolution of Language. WORLD SCIENTIFIC. doi:10.1142/9789812776129_0035. ISBN 978-981-277-611-2. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  15. ^ a b Sorce, James F.; Emde, Robert N.; Campos, Joseph J.; Klinnert, Mary D. (1985). "Maternal emotional signaling: Its effect on the visual cliff behavior of 1-year-olds". Developmental Psychology. 21 (1): 195–200. doi:10.1037/0012-1649.21.1.195. ISSN 1939-0599.
  16. ^ "The Visual Cliff Study: Eleanor J. Gibson and Richard D. Walk reels of animals on the Visual Cliff 7". 1960. doi:10.4135/9781473982055. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  17. ^ Feinman, Saul, ed. (1992). "Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy". doi:10.1007/978-1-4899-2462-9. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  18. ^ Bandura, Albert (1992), "Social Cognitive Theory of Social Referencing", Social Referencing and the Social Construction of Reality in Infancy, Springer US, pp. 175–208, ISBN 978-1-4899-2464-3, retrieved 2019-11-24
  19. ^ a b Hasson, Oren (2009-07). "Emotional Tears as Biological Signals". Evolutionary Psychology. 7 (3): 147470490900700. doi:10.1177/147470490900700302. ISSN 1474-7049. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  20. ^ Baker, Michael D.; Maner, Jon K. (2009-09-01). "Male risk-taking as a context-sensitive signaling device". Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 45 (5): 1136–1139. doi:10.1016/j.jesp.2009.06.006. ISSN 0022-1031.
  21. ^ Smith, Stephen A. (1993-07-29), "What is Contract Theory?", Contract Theory, Oxford University Press, pp. 3–38, ISBN 978-0-19-876561-5, retrieved 2019-11-24
  22. ^ "Economic Actors". TheFreeDictionary.com. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  23. ^ Spence, Michael (1973-08). "Job Market Signaling". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 87 (3): 355. doi:10.2307/1882010. ISSN 0033-5533. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  24. ^ "Stop saying 'virtue signalling'". Adam Smith Institute. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  25. ^ a b "The awful rise of 'virtue signalling'". The Spectator. 2015-04-18. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  26. ^ "What is virtue signalling? Meaning, origin and examples – here's all you need to know". The Sun. 2017-03-08. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  27. ^ a b "I invented 'virtue signalling'. Now it's taking over the world". The Spectator. 2015-10-10. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  28. ^ "Despite 'virtue signalling', words tend to fail the Right". The Centre for Independent Studies. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  29. ^ Miller, Geoffrey. Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech. ISBN 978-1-951555-00-9. OCLC 1127937178.
  30. ^ "Virtue signaling and other inane platitudes - The Boston Globe". BostonGlobe.com. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  31. ^ a b c d e f "The awful rise of 'virtue signalling'". The Spectator. 2015-04-18. Retrieved 2019-11-24.
  32. ^ Miller, Geoffrey. Virtue Signaling : Essays on Darwinian Politics & Free Speech. ISBN 978-1-951555-00-9. OCLC 1127937178.
  33. ^ a b c d e "Virtue signaling and other inane platitudes - The Boston Globe". BostonGlobe.com. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  34. ^ CNN, Eric Levenson. "The most damning line from the Correspondents' Dinner? 'Flint still doesn't have clean water'". CNN. Retrieved 2019-11-25. {{cite web}}: |last= has generic name (help)
  35. ^ "What is virtue signalling? Meaning, origin and examples – here's all you need to know". The Sun. 2017-03-08. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  36. ^ Bulbulia, Joseph; Schjoedt, Uffe (2010-07-16), "Religious Culture and Cooperative Prediction under Risk: Perspectives from Social Neuroscience", Religion, Economy, and Cooperation, DE GRUYTER, pp. 35–60, ISBN 978-3-11-024632-2, retrieved 2019-11-25
  37. ^ Bulbulia, Joseph; Atkinson, Quentin; Gray, Russell; Greenhill, Simon (2014-04), "Why do religious cultures evolve slowly? The cultural evolution of cooperative calling and the historical study of religions", http://universitypublishingonline.org/acumen/chapter.jsf?bid=CBO9781844657346&cid=CBO9781844657346A021, Acumen Publishing, ISBN 978-1-84465-734-6, retrieved 2019-11-25 {{citation}}: Check date values in: |date= (help); External link in |work= (help)
  38. ^ Jordan, Jillian; Rand, David (2019-03-30). "Opinion | Are You 'Virtue Signaling'?". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  39. ^ Shariatmadari, David (2016-01-20). "'Virtue-signalling' – the putdown that has passed its sell-by date | David Shariatmadari". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  40. ^ "Stop saying 'virtue signalling'". Adam Smith Institute. Retrieved 2019-11-25.
  41. ^ Bowman, S. (2016) Stop Saying 'Virtue Signalling' blog post for the Adam Smith Institute
  42. ^ Williams, Zoe (April 10, 2016). "Forget about Labour's heartland – it doesn't exist". The Guardian. Retrieved 2016-04-11.
  43. ^ Shariatmadari, David (January 20, 2016). "Virtue-signalling – the putdown that has passed its sell-by date". The Guardian. Retrieved 2016-04-11.
  44. ^ Robert Shrimsley (2019-05-10). "Once you're accused of virtue-signalling, you can't do anything right". Financial Times.
  45. ^ Nick Cohen (2018-05-25). "The Tories are the masters of 'vice signalling'". Spectator.
  46. ^ Ali Harb (2019-05-23). "Saudi activists and US lawmakers join call for end to 'sadistic' abuses by MBS". Middle East Eye.