Jump to content

Ferdinando Galiani: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
Cryptex (talk | contribs)
m English language editing
Line 21: Line 21:
[[File:Galiani - Della moneta, 1780 - 5762004.tif|thumb|''Della moneta'', 1780]]
[[File:Galiani - Della moneta, 1780 - 5762004.tif|thumb|''Della moneta'', 1780]]


Born at [[Chieti]], he was carefully educated by his uncle, Monsignor Celestino Galiani,<ref>See Fausto Nicolini,'' Un grande educatore italiano, Celestino Galiani'' (Naples, 1951)</ref> at [[Naples]] and [[Rome]] with a view to entering the church. Galiani showed early promise as an economist, and even more as a [[wit]]. By the age of twenty-two, after he took orders,<ref>He is usually referred to, in French contexts, as the "[[abbé]] Galiani".</ref> he had produced two works by which his name became widely known far beyond the bounds of his own Naples. The one, his ''[[Della Moneta]]'', a disquisition on coinage in which he shows himself a strong supporter of [[mercantilism]], deals with many aspects of the question of exchange, but always with a special reference to the state of confusion then presented by the whole monetary system of the Neapolitan government.
Born in [[Chieti]], he was carefully educated by his uncle, Monsignor Celestino Galiani,<ref>See Fausto Nicolini,'' Un grande educatore italiano, Celestino Galiani'' (Naples, 1951)</ref> in [[Naples]] and [[Rome]] with a view to entering the church. Galiani showed early promise as an economist, and even more as a [[wit]]. By the age of twenty-two, after he took orders,<ref>He is usually referred to, in French contexts, as the "[[abbé]] Galiani".</ref> he had produced two works by which his name became widely known far beyond the bounds of Naples. The first, ''[[Della Moneta]]'', a disquisition on coinage in which he shows himself a strong supporter of [[mercantilism]], deals with many aspects of the question of exchange, but always with a special reference to the state of confusion then presented by the monetary system of the Neapolitan government.


The other, ''Raccolta in Morte del Boia'', established his fame as a humorist, and was highly popular in Italian literary circles at the end of the 18th century. In this volume Galiani [[parody|parodied]], in a series of discourses on the death of the public hangman, the styles of Neapolitan writers of the day.<ref name=Acton>{{cite book|last=Acton|first=Harold|title=The Bourbons of Naples (1731-1825)|year=1957|publisher=Faber and Faber|location=London|isbn=9780571249015}}</ref> Galiani's political knowledge and social qualities brought him to the attention of [[Charles III of Spain|King Charles of Naples and Sicily]] (afterwards Charles III of Spain) and his liberal minister [[Bernardo Tanucci]], and in 1759 Galiani was appointed secretary to the Neapolitan embassy at Paris. This post he held for ten years, when he returned to Naples and was made a councillor of the tribunal of commerce, and in 1777 administrator of the royal domains.
The other, ''Raccolta in Morte del Boia'', established his fame as a humorist, and was highly popular in Italian literary circles at the end of the 18th century. In this volume Galiani [[parody|parodied]], in a series of discourses on the death of the public hangman, the styles of Neapolitan writers of the day.<ref name=Acton>{{cite book|last=Acton|first=Harold|title=The Bourbons of Naples (1731-1825)|year=1957|publisher=Faber and Faber|location=London|isbn=9780571249015}}</ref> Galiani's political knowledge and social qualities brought him to the attention of [[Charles III of Spain|King Charles of Naples and Sicily]] (afterwards Charles III of Spain) and his liberal minister [[Bernardo Tanucci]], and in 1759 Galiani was appointed secretary to the Neapolitan embassy in Paris. He held this post for ten years, when he returned to Naples and was made a councillor of the tribunal of commerce, and in 1777 administrator of the royal domains.


Galiani's published works focus on the area of humanities as well as social sciences. He left a large number of priceless letters which are not only of biographical interest but are also important for the light they cast on the social, economic, and political characteristics of eighteenth-century Europe. His economic reputation was made by a book written in the [[French language]] and published 1769 in [[Paris, France|Paris]], namely, his ''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds'', "Dialogues on the commerce in wheat". This work, by its light and pleasing style, and its vivacious wit, delighted [[Voltaire]], who described it as a cross between [[Plato]] and [[Molière]]. The author, says [[Giuseppe Pecchio]],<ref>Pecchio, ''Storia della economia pubblica in Italia: ossia epilogo critico'' 1829.</ref> treated his arid subject as [[Bernard le Bovier de Fontenelle|Fontenelle]] did the vortices of [[René Descartes|Descartes]], or [[Francesco, count Algarotti|Algarotti]] the [[Classical mechanics|Newtonian system of the world]]. The question at issue was that of the freedom of the corn trade, then much agitated, and, in particular, the policy of the royal edict of 1764, which permitted the exportation of grain so long as the price had not arrived at a certain height. The general principle he maintains is that the best system in regard to this trade is to have no system — countries of different circumstances requiring, according to him, different modes of treatment. He fell, however, into some of the most serious errors of the mercantilists — holding, as indeed did also Voltaire and even [[Pietro Verri]], that [[Zero sum|one country cannot gain without another losing]], and in his earlier treatise going so far as to defend the action of governments in debasing the currency. Until his death at Naples, Galiani kept up a correspondence with his old Parisian friends, notably [[Louise d'Épinay]];<ref>This correspondence furnished the material for [[Francis Steegmuller]], ''A Woman, A Man and Two Kingdoms: The story of Mme d'Épinay and the Abbé Galiani'', 1991.</ref> this was published in 1818.
Galiani's published works focus on the area of humanities as well as social sciences. He left a large number of letters which are not only of biographical interest but are also important for the light they cast on the social, economic, and political characteristics of eighteenth-century Europe. His economic reputation was mainly due to his book written in [[French language|French]] and published 1769 in [[Paris, France|Paris]], namely, his ''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds'', "Dialogues on the commerce in wheat". This work, by its light and pleasing style, and its vivacious wit, delighted [[Voltaire]], who described it as a cross between [[Plato]] and [[Molière]]. The author, says [[Giuseppe Pecchio]],<ref>Pecchio, ''Storia della economia pubblica in Italia: ossia epilogo critico'' 1829.</ref> treated his arid subject as [[Bernard le Bovier de Fontenelle|Fontenelle]] did the vortices of [[René Descartes|Descartes]], or [[Francesco, count Algarotti|Algarotti]] the [[Classical mechanics|Newtonian system of the world]]. The question at issue was that of the freedom of the corn trade, then much agitated, and, in particular, the policy of the royal edict of 1764, which permitted the exportation of grain so long as the price had not reached a certain level. The general principle he maintains is that the best system in regard to this trade is to have no system — countries in different circumstances requiring, according to him, different modes of treatment. He fell, however, into some of the most serious errors of the mercantilists — holding, as indeed did also Voltaire and even [[Pietro Verri]], that [[Zero sum|one country cannot gain without another losing]], and in his earlier treatise going so far as to defend the action of governments in debasing the currency. Until his death in Naples, Galiani kept up a correspondence with his old Parisian friends, notably [[Louise d'Épinay]];<ref>This correspondence furnished the material for [[Francis Steegmuller]], ''A Woman, A Man and Two Kingdoms: The story of Mme d'Épinay and the Abbé Galiani'', 1991.</ref> this was published in 1818.


See ''L'abate Galiani'', by [[Alberto Marghieri]] (1878), and his correspondence with Tanucci in [[Giampietro Vieusseux]]'s ''L'Archivio storico'' (Florence, 1878).
See ''L'abate Galiani'', by [[Alberto Marghieri]] (1878), and his correspondence with Tanucci in [[Giampietro Vieusseux]]'s ''L'Archivio storico'' (Florence, 1878).
Line 32: Line 32:
===''Della moneta''===
===''Della moneta''===
{{Main|Della Moneta}}
{{Main|Della Moneta}}
In 1751, while still a student, Galiani written a book entitled ''Della moneta'' which intervened in the Neapolitan debate on economic reform. In this book, he discussed financial politics and gave opinions on how to develop the Neapolitan economy. At the same time, he proposed a theory of value based on utility and scarcity; this depth of thinking on economic value would not be seen again until discussions of marginal utility developed in the 1870s. In addition, Galiani's tract exhibited conventional Mercantilist ideas and some of his recommendations were adopted by the Neapolitan government.
In 1751, while still a student, Galiani wrote a book entitled ''Della moneta'' which intervened in the Neapolitan debate on economic reform. In this book, he discussed financial politics and gave opinions on how to develop the Neapolitan economy. At the same time, he proposed a theory of value based on utility and scarcity; this depth of thinking on economic value would not be seen again until discussions of marginal utility developed in the 1870s. In addition, Galiani's tract exhibited conventional Mercantilist ideas and some of his recommendations were adopted by the Neapolitan government.


The Chapter 1 of Book I introduces the history of money as well as the rise and fall of states in antiquity and modern times. By using historical examples, Galiani pointed out his idea that commerce was neglected by political rulers throughout the whole history of humankind. States could become rich and grew through the conquest, however they still could not enhance their power, territory and wealth without commerce.
Chapter 1 of Book I introduces the history of money as well as the rise and fall of states in antiquity and modern times. By using historical examples, Galiani illustrated his idea that commerce was neglected by political rulers throughout the whole history of humankind. States could become rich and grew through the conquest; however, they could not enhance their power, territory and wealth without commerce.


In the core chapter of the book, Galiani explained that the value of money at any point in time derived from principles that were part of human nature itself; money was definitely not a human invention by which people deliberately changed the societies they lived in. Money generated naturally from the gradual modification of people's loves into social ideas of value that inspired commercial interaction. Money exists without relying on promises, trust, or another moral capacity of self-restraint and money is not created by agreement. If this situation is changed, commerce could not be the central of modern societies
In the core chapter of the book, Galiani explained that the value of money at any point in time derived from principles that were part of human nature itself; money was definitely not a human invention by which people deliberately changed the societies they lived in. Money generated naturally from the gradual modification of people's loves into social ideas of value that inspired commercial interaction. Money exists without relying on promises, trust, or another moral capacity of self-restraint and money is not created by an agreement. If this situation was changed, commerce could not be the centre of modern societies


In Della moneta, Galiani constantly described the effects of human actions in terms of providential rewards and punishments. He used the term providence to reconcile the historical dynamic of commercial progress with a set of fixed moral rules that lay at the core of successful human interaction. Galiani presented any moralistic dismissals of natural price formation and self-interested profit-seeking as reproaches to the way God intended human societies to function. Providential mechanisms were also involved in the history of money, the rise and fall of states in both antiquity and modernity and regulated the development of cultural characteristics of the dominant societies in the course of time. Throughout history man constantly reshaped the fictional moral beliefs, thereby creating the mental preconditions for commercial society.
In ''Della moneta'', Galiani constantly described the effects of human actions in terms of providential rewards and punishments. He used the term "providence" to reconcile the historical dynamic of commercial progress with a set of fixed moral rules that lay at the core of successful human interaction. Galiani presented any moralistic dismissals of natural price formation and self-interested profit-seeking as reproaches to the way God intended human societies to function. Providential mechanisms were also involved in the history of money, the rise and fall of states in both antiquity and modernity and regulated the development of cultural characteristics of the dominant societies in the course of time. Throughout history man constantly reshaped the fictional moral beliefs, thereby creating the mental preconditions for commercial society.


===''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds''===
===''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds''===
During the period of being a diplomat in Paris, Galiani wrote ''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds'', which emphasized the importance for the regulation of commerce—an argument that opposed the [[Physiocracy|physiocrats]], who advocated complete freedom. This book was published in 1770 and Galiani indicated in this book that there are increasing returns to manufacturing, and diminishing returns to agriculture, and the wealth of a nation depends on manufacturing and trade. Although approving of the edict of 1764 liberalizing the grain trade, Galiani rejected much of the physiocratic analysis, notably its "land theory of value". His 1770 piece also provided a quite modern analysis of balance of payments.
During the period of being a diplomat in Paris, Galiani wrote ''Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds'', which emphasized the importance for the regulation of commerce — an argument that opposed the [[Physiocracy|physiocrats]], who advocated complete freedom. This book was published in 1770 and Galiani indicated in this book that there are increasing returns to manufacturing, and diminishing returns to agriculture and the wealth of a nation depends on manufacturing and trade. Although approving of the edict of 1764 liberalizing the grain trade, Galiani rejected much of the physiocratic analysis, notably its "land theory of value". His 1770 piece also provided a quite modern analysis of the balance of payments.


In the Dialogues, Galiani described that wheat can be seen at two different aspects. The distinctions between two different aspects is important, as a product of the earth, wheat can be considered both commerce and economic legislation. As a product of first necessity, wheat is a symbol of social order and belongs to administration. As Galiani put it in an illuminating way, ‘As soon as supplying [wheat] is the concern of administration, it is no longer an object of commerce’. Correspondingly, ‘It is certain that what is sensible and useful from one standpoint, becomes absurd and harmful from another’.
In the Dialogues, Galiani described that wheat can be seen in two different aspects. The distinctions between two different aspects are important: as a product of the earth, wheat can be considered both commerce and economic legislation. As a product of first necessity, wheat is a symbol of social order and belongs to administration. As Galiani put it in an illuminating way, ‘As soon as supplying [wheat] is the concern of administration, it is no longer an object of commerce’. Correspondingly, ‘It is certain that what is sensible and useful from one standpoint, becomes absurd and harmful from another’.


Galiani believed that there are many shocks to economy, which can cause disequilibrium and it takes long time for the restoration of equilibrium. He thanked that something instead of the nature law needed to face the challenge and shocks. Administration dealt with the ‘sudden movements’ of the economy, such as shortages in the wheat supply. In other words, the legislator could not but consider the down-to-earth constraints of subsistence. In this respect, the physiocratic enlightened despot consistently and independently ruling economic matters according to natural laws was not enough to maintain social order.
Galiani believed that there are many shocks to the economy, which can cause disequilibrium and it takes long time for the restoration of equilibrium. He thanked that something instead of the natural law needed to face the challenge and shocks. Administration dealt with the ‘sudden movements’ of the economy, such as shortages in the wheat supply. In other words, the legislator could not but consider the down-to-earth constraints of subsistence. In this respect, the physiocratic enlightened despot consistently and independently ruling economic matters according to natural laws was not enough to maintain social order.


==Attitude to physiocrats==
==Attitude to physiocrats==

Revision as of 22:12, 3 August 2020

Ferdinando Galiani.

Ferdinando Galiani (2 December 1728, Chieti, Kingdom of Naples – 30 October 1787, Naples, Kingdom of Naples) was an Italian economist, a leading Italian figure of the Enlightenment. Friedrich Nietzsche referred to him as "a most fastidious and refined intelligence" [1] as well as "... the most profound, sharp-sighted and perhaps also the foulest man of his century." [2]

Biography

Della moneta, 1780

Born in Chieti, he was carefully educated by his uncle, Monsignor Celestino Galiani,[3] in Naples and Rome with a view to entering the church. Galiani showed early promise as an economist, and even more as a wit. By the age of twenty-two, after he took orders,[4] he had produced two works by which his name became widely known far beyond the bounds of Naples. The first, Della Moneta, a disquisition on coinage in which he shows himself a strong supporter of mercantilism, deals with many aspects of the question of exchange, but always with a special reference to the state of confusion then presented by the monetary system of the Neapolitan government.

The other, Raccolta in Morte del Boia, established his fame as a humorist, and was highly popular in Italian literary circles at the end of the 18th century. In this volume Galiani parodied, in a series of discourses on the death of the public hangman, the styles of Neapolitan writers of the day.[5] Galiani's political knowledge and social qualities brought him to the attention of King Charles of Naples and Sicily (afterwards Charles III of Spain) and his liberal minister Bernardo Tanucci, and in 1759 Galiani was appointed secretary to the Neapolitan embassy in Paris. He held this post for ten years, when he returned to Naples and was made a councillor of the tribunal of commerce, and in 1777 administrator of the royal domains.

Galiani's published works focus on the area of humanities as well as social sciences. He left a large number of letters which are not only of biographical interest but are also important for the light they cast on the social, economic, and political characteristics of eighteenth-century Europe. His economic reputation was mainly due to his book written in French and published 1769 in Paris, namely, his Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds, "Dialogues on the commerce in wheat". This work, by its light and pleasing style, and its vivacious wit, delighted Voltaire, who described it as a cross between Plato and Molière. The author, says Giuseppe Pecchio,[6] treated his arid subject as Fontenelle did the vortices of Descartes, or Algarotti the Newtonian system of the world. The question at issue was that of the freedom of the corn trade, then much agitated, and, in particular, the policy of the royal edict of 1764, which permitted the exportation of grain so long as the price had not reached a certain level. The general principle he maintains is that the best system in regard to this trade is to have no system — countries in different circumstances requiring, according to him, different modes of treatment. He fell, however, into some of the most serious errors of the mercantilists — holding, as indeed did also Voltaire and even Pietro Verri, that one country cannot gain without another losing, and in his earlier treatise going so far as to defend the action of governments in debasing the currency. Until his death in Naples, Galiani kept up a correspondence with his old Parisian friends, notably Louise d'Épinay;[7] this was published in 1818.

See L'abate Galiani, by Alberto Marghieri (1878), and his correspondence with Tanucci in Giampietro Vieusseux's L'Archivio storico (Florence, 1878).

Published works

Della moneta

In 1751, while still a student, Galiani wrote a book entitled Della moneta which intervened in the Neapolitan debate on economic reform. In this book, he discussed financial politics and gave opinions on how to develop the Neapolitan economy. At the same time, he proposed a theory of value based on utility and scarcity; this depth of thinking on economic value would not be seen again until discussions of marginal utility developed in the 1870s. In addition, Galiani's tract exhibited conventional Mercantilist ideas and some of his recommendations were adopted by the Neapolitan government.

Chapter 1 of Book I introduces the history of money as well as the rise and fall of states in antiquity and modern times. By using historical examples, Galiani illustrated his idea that commerce was neglected by political rulers throughout the whole history of humankind. States could become rich and grew through the conquest; however, they could not enhance their power, territory and wealth without commerce.

In the core chapter of the book, Galiani explained that the value of money at any point in time derived from principles that were part of human nature itself; money was definitely not a human invention by which people deliberately changed the societies they lived in. Money generated naturally from the gradual modification of people's loves into social ideas of value that inspired commercial interaction. Money exists without relying on promises, trust, or another moral capacity of self-restraint and money is not created by an agreement. If this situation was changed, commerce could not be the centre of modern societies

In Della moneta, Galiani constantly described the effects of human actions in terms of providential rewards and punishments. He used the term "providence" to reconcile the historical dynamic of commercial progress with a set of fixed moral rules that lay at the core of successful human interaction. Galiani presented any moralistic dismissals of natural price formation and self-interested profit-seeking as reproaches to the way God intended human societies to function. Providential mechanisms were also involved in the history of money, the rise and fall of states in both antiquity and modernity and regulated the development of cultural characteristics of the dominant societies in the course of time. Throughout history man constantly reshaped the fictional moral beliefs, thereby creating the mental preconditions for commercial society.

Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds

During the period of being a diplomat in Paris, Galiani wrote Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds, which emphasized the importance for the regulation of commerce — an argument that opposed the physiocrats, who advocated complete freedom. This book was published in 1770 and Galiani indicated in this book that there are increasing returns to manufacturing, and diminishing returns to agriculture and the wealth of a nation depends on manufacturing and trade. Although approving of the edict of 1764 liberalizing the grain trade, Galiani rejected much of the physiocratic analysis, notably its "land theory of value". His 1770 piece also provided a quite modern analysis of the balance of payments.

In the Dialogues, Galiani described that wheat can be seen in two different aspects. The distinctions between two different aspects are important: as a product of the earth, wheat can be considered both commerce and economic legislation. As a product of first necessity, wheat is a symbol of social order and belongs to administration. As Galiani put it in an illuminating way, ‘As soon as supplying [wheat] is the concern of administration, it is no longer an object of commerce’. Correspondingly, ‘It is certain that what is sensible and useful from one standpoint, becomes absurd and harmful from another’.

Galiani believed that there are many shocks to the economy, which can cause disequilibrium and it takes long time for the restoration of equilibrium. He thanked that something instead of the natural law needed to face the challenge and shocks. Administration dealt with the ‘sudden movements’ of the economy, such as shortages in the wheat supply. In other words, the legislator could not but consider the down-to-earth constraints of subsistence. In this respect, the physiocratic enlightened despot consistently and independently ruling economic matters according to natural laws was not enough to maintain social order.

Attitude to physiocrats

Galiani not only has theoretical brilliance with his idea of “natural” laws in economics, but also was a practical man, skeptical about the reach of abstract theory, particularly when action was necessary and urgent. He was repelled by the wide-eyed policies called for by the physiocrats, which he believed were, unrealistic, impractical and, in times of crisis, downright dangerous.

Galiani disagreed the physiocratic argument which is said that in order to provide a sufficient supply of grain, it suffices to establish a completely free trade. In fact, the foreign trade agreed with the physiocrats that internal free trade can benefit the economy. However, Galiani used the case of exportation to challenge the physiocrats. At one point in the Dialogues, he even stated: ‘Here I am not talking about the internal liberty of trade… Let us talk foreign trade’ (Galiani 1770, 224-5). Whereas the physiocrats advocated total liberty both domestically and internationally, Galiani believed internal liberty was the first priority. Even though he was not totally opposed to grain exportation, Galiani often condemned the physiocratic liberty to export grain. Precisely, he argued that the foreign trade can threaten domestic liberty, for the frontier provinces of the kingdom may find foreign markets more attractive than domestic ones. Therefore, as long as there is no certainty as to the existence of a permanent surplus, Galiani claimed, the nation must concentrate its efforts on the internal circulation of grain.

For him, the physiocrats were a dangerous group of impractical men with wrong ideas. In 1768, as France collapsed in a near-famine, the physiocrats still called for "non-action", muttering on their ordre naturel and the glorious wisdom of Quesnay, which galvanized of making their own remarkable contributions in opposition.

Works

  • Della moneta, 1750
  • Dialogues sur le commerce des bleds, 1770
  • Doveri dei prìncipi neutrali, 1782

References

  1. ^ Nietzsche, Friedrich (1996). Christopher Middleton (ed.). Selected letters of Friedrich Nietzsche. Translated by Middleton. Hackett Publishing. p. 274. ISBN 0-87220-358-1.
  2. ^ Nietzsche, Friedrich (1886). "II 26". Jenseits von Gut und Böse (Beyond Good and Evil). Ian Johnston (trans.).
  3. ^ See Fausto Nicolini, Un grande educatore italiano, Celestino Galiani (Naples, 1951)
  4. ^ He is usually referred to, in French contexts, as the "abbé Galiani".
  5. ^ Acton, Harold (1957). The Bourbons of Naples (1731-1825). London: Faber and Faber. ISBN 9780571249015.
  6. ^ Pecchio, Storia della economia pubblica in Italia: ossia epilogo critico 1829.
  7. ^ This correspondence furnished the material for Francis Steegmuller, A Woman, A Man and Two Kingdoms: The story of Mme d'Épinay and the Abbé Galiani, 1991.

Sources