Retail concentration
Retail concentration refers to the market-share generally belonging to the top 4 or 5 mass distribution firms present in a regional market, as a percentage of the total.
Retail concentration is not simply a concentration ratio as is emerging in the food sector. This is due to two factors: the particular relevance retail is gaining on a global scale, and the particular shape of the food supply chain.
In recent years, Retail Concentration moved ahead with fusions and acquisitions[1] along the entire food supply chain.[2] We can assume with Grievink (2003) that in a few years there will be only 5 dominant actors in the globalised food chain.[3] The same researcher states that in the 90's the top-5 food manufacturers could count on twice the cash flow of the top-5 retailers. Nowadays the relation is inverted: the top 5 retailers can count on twice that of the top-5 manufacturers.[citation needed]
Thus, the food chain has become increasingly vertically integrated, with global corporations able to coordinate inputs from the seed to the field, from the stable to the table. Retail concentration by one hand is the answer that retail is giving to compete with the giants of agrofood industry. By the other hand, is the agrofood industry in itself searching to arrive directly to the consumers, through a refined relations system. In this process, private labels are increasingly attracting consumers, and are expected to grow more and more on their fidelisation strategy, beating on quality, safety and also ethical values.[4]
Recently the European Commission[5] proposed solutions to face with overall price increase about foodstuff. Among the measures proposed, several relate to the retail power recently acquired.
In particular, the payments delay to the producers; the additional fees asked to the producers to place on the shelves branded products; price transparency; better regulation on promotional activities and openings/closing time are all issues on the agenda.
For supporters, retail concentration means more chances for consumers, lower prices, better quality. For opponents, by the contrary, the disappearing of traditional shops, of food culture, of neighborhood life in general.[6] Furthermore, too much concentration means squeezing the price of industry and of agriculture, which can lead to outsourcing food from anywhere it can cost less, without a truly long term impact assessment.
Tim Lang (Food Wars, Earthscan London 2004) described the retail concentration phenomenon such as a "food war", in which winners and losers take place. Tim Lang talks about "food clusters" ([p. 84]) to better handle the idea of concentration along the entire food chain. There are a lot of legal instruments which allow to get more and more concentrated. Acquisition being the first one, follow mergers, joint ventures, partnerships and more not formalised contracts/ agreements. Note that the "hypermarketization" is not limited to the Western World, but supermarkets rise fast also in the less developed countries and in the East and in the South of the World. .[7] Regarding that, there are a lot of concerns, pretending that the overwhelming power of retailing is making poorer and poorer farmers, in particular in the LDC (Less Developed Countries).[8] The "crowding out" effect on local agricultures it is basically due to the global sourcing of the produces, wherever they cost less and offer more. To say it with the words of the Italian food-thinker Corrado Finardi to fairly function, the agricultural system has a different, slower timeline than the market (in agriculture counts the long term investment, while on the global market it is more important the precise moment in which supply and demand match).
Market concentration (considering the upper and lower tails) A more refined form, which calculates the percentage of last 4/ competitors on the first 4/5. Eve in its static version, it measures the level of competition in the sector. A diachronic comparison allows for even more insights.
Herfindahl Hirschman Index This index is used in Europe and in the USA for antitrust regulatory purposes, in order to assess the feasibility of mergers and acquisitions. The HHI is calculated as the relative frequencies squared and summed, comprehensive of all actors in the playfield. So far, it gives more importance to biggest player in proportion. Even if interesting, a HHI, often wrongly assess the real behaviours on the field. Consider, for the comparison sake, the retail concentration in Europe. Top 5 retail distributors account for the 70% of the market share. Even if apparently it gives the idea of a highly concentrated market, the HHI does not allow for that conclusion in most of the cases. Following 3 different scenarios, we explored the relative market shares of the single actors. 1 scenario: 1= 19%, 2=15%, 3=14%, 4= 12%, 5=10% (total=70% for the top 5), remaining= 2%, 3%, 4%, 5%, 7%, 9%. In this first case, where there is a linear distribution of market share among players, the HHI scores at 0,121 (considered a moderate concentration indicator)
2 scenario: 14% *5 (top 5 players =70%, having equal market share), the remaining, each equalling 3% (3%*10). In this second case, the HHI scores an 0,098, which stands for an unconcentrated market at all. We can deliberately make some reflections on that, since the HHI seems not taking into account opportunistic behaviours in the direction of oligopoly. It is assumed that, because of the equal market power of the top 5 actors, they are going to compete (even if history shows that more probably they find some form of implicit agreement…). Standardised from 0 to 1, the value is 0,033571429 (very low…).
3 scenario. First player= 20%, followers 12%, then 10%, 9%, 8%, 7%, 4% and the last 10 each 3%. In this case the HHI is 0,0944 (not concentrated market, even if not highly competitive environment). Standardised from 0 to 1, the value is 0,0378 (very low…).
Even in a case where there is one leading competitor which “makes the market” as in the 3rd scenario, the HHI stays relatively low.
See also
References
- ^ http://www.capgemini.com/resources/news/consumers_drive_food_industry_transformation__global_brands_retail_formats_consolidation__says_new_report/[full citation needed]
- ^ "Increasing retail concentration: Evidence from the UK food retail". British Food Journal vol. 106. 2004. doi:10.1108/00070700410553611. Retrieved 2012-07-07.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite journal requires|journal=
(help) - ^ https://web.archive.org/web/20081204235802/http://www.foodinternational.net/articles/efi-special/1249/state-of-the-art-in-food.html. Archived from the original on December 4, 2008. Retrieved December 10, 2008.
{{cite web}}
: Missing or empty|title=
(help) - ^ http://www.foodinternational.net/articles/efi-special/583/private-labels-why-europe-is-leading-the-pack.html [dead link ]
- ^ http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/thematic_articles/article13524_en.htm [full citation needed]
- ^ International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity, 2006 3: 33 “Understanding environmental influences on nutrition and physical activity behaviors: where should we look and what should we count?”, Kylie Ball, Anna F Timperio and David A Crawford
- ^ Chowdhury, Shyamal; Ashok Gulati; E. Gumbira Sa'id (June–December 2005). "The Rise of Supermarkets and Vertical Relationships in the Indonesian Food Value Chain" (PDF). Asian Journal of Agriculture and Development. 2 (1 & 2). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2008-12-03. Retrieved 2008-12-10.
- ^ http://www.agobservatory.org/library.cfm?RefID=46604 [dead link ]