Stable roommates problem
In mathematics, economics and computer science, particularly in the fields of combinatorics, game theory and algorithms, the stable-roommate problem (SRP) is the problem of finding a stable matching for an even-sized set. A matching is a separation of the set into disjoint pairs ("roommates"). The matching is stable if there are no two elements which are not roommates and which both prefer each other to their roommate under the matching. This is distinct from the stable-marriage problem in that the stable-roommates problem allows matches between any two elements, not just between classes of "men" and "women".
It is commonly stated as:
- In a given instance of the stable-roommates problem (SRP), each of 2n participants ranks the others in strict order of preference. A matching is a set of n disjoint pairs of participants. A matching M in an instance of SRP is stable if there are no two participants x and y, each of whom prefers the other to their partner in M. Such a pair is said to block M, or to be a blocking pair with respect to M.
Solution
Unlike the stable marriage problem, a stable matching may fail to exist for certain sets of participants and their preferences. For a minimal example of a stable pairing not existing, consider 4 people A, B, C, and D, whose rankings are:
- A:(B,C,D), B:(C,A,D), C:(A,B,D), D:(A,B,C)
In this ranking, each of A, B, and C is the most preferable person for someone. In any solution, one of A, B, or C must be paired with D and the other two with each other (for example AD and BC), yet for anyone who is partnered with D, another member will have rated them highest, and D’s partner will in turn prefer this other member over D. In this example, AC is a more favorable pairing than AD, but the necessary remaining pairing of BD then raises the same issue, illustrating the absence of a stable matching for these participants and their preferences.
Algorithm
An efficient algorithm was given in (Irving 1985).[1] The algorithm will determine, for any instance of the problem, whether a stable matching exists, and if so, will find such a matching. Irving’s algorithm has O(n2) complexity, provided suitable data structures are used to implement the necessary manipulation of the preference lists and identification of rotations.
The algorithm consists of two phases. In Phase 1, participants propose to each other, in a manner similar to that of the Gale-Shapley algorithm for the stable marriage problem. Each participant orders the other members by preference, resulting in a preference list—an ordered set of the other participants. Participants then propose to each person on their list, in order, continuing to the next person if and when their current proposal is rejected. A participant will reject a proposal if they already hold a proposal from someone they prefer. A participant will also reject a previously-accepted proposal if they later receive a proposal that they prefer. In this case, the rejected participant will then propose to the next person on their list, continuing until a proposal is again accepted. If any participant is eventually rejected by all other participants, this indicates that no stable matching is possible. Otherwise, Phase 1 will end with each person holding a proposal from one of the others.
Consider two participants, q and p. If q holds a proposal from p, then we remove from q's list all participants x after p, and symmetrically, for each removed participant x, we remove q from x's list, so that q is first in p's list; and p, last in q's, since q and any x cannot be partners in any stable matching. The resulting reduced set of preference lists together is called the Phase 1 table. In this table, if any reduced list is empty, then there is no stable matching. Otherwise, the Phase 1 table is a stable table. A stable table, by definition, is the set of preference lists from the original table after members have been removed from one or more of the lists, and the following three conditions are satisfied (where reduced list means a list in the stable table):
(i) p is first on q's reduced list if and only if q is last on p's
(ii) p is not on q's reduced list if and only if q is not on p's if and only if q prefers the last person on their list to p; or p, the last person on their list to q
(iii) no reduced list is empty
Stable tables have several important properties, which are used to justify the remainder of the procedure:
- Any stable table must be a subtable of the Phase 1 table, where subtable is a table where the preference lists of the subtable are those of the supertable with some individuals removed from each other's lists.
- In any stable table, if every reduced list contains exactly one individual, then pairing each individual with the single person on their list gives a stable matching.
- If the stable roommates problem instance has a stable matching, then there is a stable matching contained in any one of the stable tables.
- Any stable subtable of a stable table, and in particular any stable subtable that specifies a stable matching as in 2, can be obtained by a sequence of rotation eliminations on the stable table.
These rotation eliminations comprise Phase 2 of Irving’s algorithm.
By 2, if each reduced list of the Phase 1 table contains exactly one individual, then this gives a matching.
Otherwise, the algorithm enters Phase 2. A rotation in a stable table T is defined as a sequence (x0, y0), (x1, y1), ..., (xk-1, yk-1) such that the xi are distinct, yi is first on xi's reduced list (or xi is last on yi's reduced list) and yi+1 is second on xi's reduced list, for i = 0, ..., k-1 where the indices are taken modulo k. It follows that in any stable table with a reduced list containing at least two individuals, such a rotation always exists. To find it, start at such a p0 containing at least two individuals in their reduced list, and define recursively qi+1 to be the second on pi's list and pi+1 to be the last on qi+1's list, until this sequence repeats some pj, at which point a rotation is found: it is the sequence of pairs starting at the first occurrence of (pj, qj) and ending at the pair before the last occurrence. The sequence of pi up until the pj is called the tail of the rotation. The fact that it's a stable table in which this search occurs guarantees that each pi has at least two individuals on their list.
To eliminate the rotation, yi rejects xi so that xi proposes to yi+1, for each i. To restore the stable table properties (i) and (ii), for each i, all successors of xi-1 are removed from yi's list, and yi is removed from their lists. If a reduced list becomes empty during these removals, then there is no stable matching. Otherwise, the new table is again a stable table, and either already specifies a matching since each list contains exactly one individual or there remains another rotation to find and eliminate, so the step is repeated.
Phase 2 of the algorithm can now be summarized as follows:
T = Phase 1 table;
while (true) {
identify a rotation r in T;
eliminate r from T;
if some list in T becomes empty,
return null; (no stable matching can exist)
else if (each reduced list in T has size 1)
return the matching M = {{x, y} | x and y are on each other's lists in T}; (this is a stable matching)
}
To achieve an O(n2) running time, a ranking matrix whose entry at row i and column j is the position of the jth individual in the ith's list; this takes O(n2) time. With the ranking matrix, checking whether an individual prefers one to another can be done in constant time by comparing their ranks in the matrix. Furthermore, instead of explicitly removing elements from the preference lists, the indices of the first, second and last on each individual's reduced list are maintained. The first individual that is unmatched, i.e. has at least two in their reduced lists, is also maintained. Then, in Phase 2, the sequence of pi "traversed" to find a rotation is stored in a list, and an array is used to mark individuals as having been visited, as in a standard depth-first search graph traversal. After the elimination of a rotation, we continue to store only its tail, if any, in the list and as visited in the array, and start the search for the next rotation at the last individual on the tail, and otherwise at the next unmatched individual if there is no tail. This reduces repeated traversal of the tail, since it is largely unaffected by the elimination of the rotation.
Example
The following are the preference lists for a Stable Roommates instance involving 6 participants: 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6.
1 : 3 4 2 6 5
2 : 6 5 4 1 3
3 : 2 4 5 1 6
4 : 5 2 3 6 1
5 : 3 1 2 4 6
6 : 5 1 3 4 2
A possible execution of Phase 1 consists of the following sequence of proposals and rejections, where → represents proposes to and × represents rejects.
1 → 3
2 → 6
3 → 2
4 → 5
5 → 3; 3 × 1
1 → 4
6 → 5; 5 × 6
6 → 1
So Phase 1 ends with the following reduced preference lists:
1 : 3 4 2 6 5
2 : 6 5 4 1 3
3 : 2 4 5 1 6
4 : 5 2 3 6 1
5 : 3 1 2 4 6
6 : 5 1 3 4 2
In Phase 2, the rotation r1 = (1,4), (3,2) is first identified. This is because 2 is 1's second favorite, and 4 is the second favorite of 3. Eliminating r1 gives:
1 : 3 4 2 6 5
2 : 6 5 4 1 3
3 : 2 4 5 1 6
4 : 5 2 3 6 1
5 : 3 1 2 4 6
6 : 5 1 3 4 2
Next, the rotation r2 = (1,2), (2,6), (4,5) is identified, and its elimination yields:
1 : 3 4 2 6 5
2 : 6 5 4 1 3
3 : 2 4 5 1 6
4 : 5 2 3 6 1
5 : 3 1 2 4 6
6 : 5 1 3 4 2
Hence 1 and 6 are matched. Finally, the rotation r3 = (2,5), (3,4) is identified, and its elimination gives:
1 : 3 4 2 6 5
2 : 6 5 4 1 3
3 : 2 4 5 1 6
4 : 5 2 3 6 1
5 : 3 1 2 4 6
6 : 5 1 3 4 2
Hence the matching {{1, 6}, {2,4}, {3, 5}} is stable.
Implementation in software packages
- Python: An implementation of Irving's algorithm is available as part of the
matching
library.[2] - Java: A constraint programming model to find all stable matchings in the roommates problem with incomplete lists is available under the CRAPL licence.[3][4]
- R: The same constraint programming model is also available as part of the R
matchingMarkets
package.[5][6] - API: The MatchingTools API provides a free application programming interface for the algorithm.[7]
- Web Application: The "Dyad Finder" website provides a free, web-based implementation of the algorithm, including source code for the website and solver written in JavaScript.[8]
- Matlab: The algorithm is implemented in the
assignStableRoommates
function that is part of the United States Naval Research Laboratory's free Tracker Component Library[9].
References
- ^ Irving, Robert W. (1985), "An efficient algorithm for the "stable roommates" problem", Journal of Algorithms, 6 (4): 577–595, doi:10.1016/0196-6774(85)90033-1
- ^ Wilde, H.; Knight, V.; Gillard, J. (2020). "Matching: A Python library for solving matching games". Journal of Open Source Software. doi:10.21105/joss.02169.
- ^ Prosser, P. (2014). "Stable Roommates and Constraint Programming" (PDF). Lecture Notes in Computer Science, CPAIOR 2014 Edition, Springer International Publishing. 8451: 15–28.
- ^ "Constraint encoding for stable roommates problem". Java release.
- ^ Klein, T. (2015). "Analysis of Stable Matchings in R: Package matchingMarkets" (PDF). Vignette to R Package MatchingMarkets.
- ^ "matchingMarkets: Analysis of Stable Matchings". R Project. 2019-02-04.
- ^ "MatchingTools API".
- ^ "Dyad Finder". dyad-finder.web.app. Retrieved 2020-05-06.
- ^ "Tracker Component Library". Matlab Repository. Retrieved January 5, 2019.
Further reading
- Fleiner, Tamás; Irving, Robert W.; Manlove, David F. (2007), "An efficient algorithm for the "stable roommates" problem", Theoretical Computer Science, 381 (1–3): 162–176, doi:10.1016/j.tcs.2007.04.029
- Gusfield, Daniel M.; Irving, Robert W. (1989), The Stable Marriage Problem: Structure and Algorithms, MIT Press
- Irving, Robert W.; Manlove, David F. (2002), "The Stable Roommates Problem with Ties" (PDF), Journal of Algorithms, 43 (1): 85–105, CiteSeerX 10.1.1.108.7366, doi:10.1006/jagm.2002.1219