John Rust

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by KasparBot (talk | contribs) at 16:02, 16 June 2016 (migrating Persondata to Wikidata, please help, see challenges for this article). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

John P. Rust
jrust.jpg
John Rust at his house in 2011
Born (1955-05-23) May 23, 1955 (age 68)
NationalityUnited States
Alma materMassachusetts Institute of Technology, PhD (1983)
Known forStructural estimation of dynamic models of discrete choice
AwardsFrisch Medal (1992)
Scientific career
FieldsMicroeconomics, Microeconometrics
InstitutionsGeorgetown University,
University of Maryland,
Yale University,
University of Wisconsin
ThesisStationary Equilibrium in a Market for Durable Assets
Doctoral advisorDaniel McFadden
WebsitePersonal webpage

John Philip Rust (born May 23, 1955) is an American economist and econometrician. John Rust received his PhD from MIT in 1983 and taught at the University of Wisconsin, Yale University and University of Maryland before joining Georgetown University in 2012. John Rust was awarded Frisch Medal in 1992 and became the fellow of Econometric Society in 1993. [1] [2]

John Rust is best known as one of the founding fathers of the structural estimation of dynamic discrete choice models[3] and the developer of the nested fixed point (NFXP) maximum likelihood estimator which is widely used in structural econometrics. [4] However, he had published papers on broad range of topics including equilibrium in the markets of durable goods, social security, retirement, disability insurance, nuclear power industry, real estate economics, rental car industry, transportation research, auction markets, computational economics, dynamic games. [5]


Education and career

John Rust was born in Wisconsin on May 23, 1955. He graduated from Waukesha High School in 1973, completed B.A. in Mathematics in 1977 at the University of Pennsylvania, and received his Ph.D. in Economics from Massachusetts Institute of Technology in 1983. His dissertation titled “Stationary Equilibrium in a Market for Durable Assets” under the supervision of Daniel McFadden was published as Econometrica article in 1985. [6]

After graduating from University of Pennsylvania in 1977 for two year John Rust worked as research analyst for Morgan Stanley in New York City. His first academic job was at the University of Wisconsin (assistant professor, 1983-1987, associate professor, 1987-1989, and full professor, 1990-1996), after which he had professorial positions at Yale University (1996-2001) and University of Maryland (2001-2011) before starting his current affiliation with Georgetown University. [7]

John Rust had been affiliated with a number of governmental bodies, including Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System (research consultant, 1995), Panel of Expert Reviewers of Social Security Administration’s MINT Model (member, 1998-1999), Technical Panel of Social Security Advisory Board (member, 1998-1999), Long Term Modeling Advisory Group U.S. Congressional Budget Office (member, 2001-2004), Social Security Administration (advisor for demonstration project resulting from the 1999 Work Incentives Improvement Act, 2000-2003). He has also been a member of Steering Committee of the Health and Retirement Study at University of Michigan (2000-2002), senior advisor at The Brattle Group (since 2004) and fellow of TIAA-CREF Institute, New York (since 2005). [8]

Research and contributions

Bus engine replacement model

The bus engine replacement model developed in the seminal paper Rust, John (1987). "Optimal Replacement of GMC Bus Engines: An Empirical Model of Harold Zurcher". Econometrica. 55 (5). The Econometric Society: 999–1033. doi:10.2307/1911259. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1911259. is one of the first dynamic stochastic models of discrete choice estimated using real data, and continues to serve as classical example of the problems of this type. [9]

The model is a simple regenerative optimal stopping stochastic dynamic problem faced by the decision maker, Harold Zurcher, superintendent of maintenance at the Madison (Wisconsin) Metropolitan Bus Company. For every bus in operation in each time period Harold Zurcher has to decide whether to replace the engine and bear the associated replacement cost, or to continue operating the bus at an ever raising cost of operation, which includes insurance and the cost of lost ridership in the case of a breakdown.

Let denote the odometer reading (mileage) at period , cost of operating the bus which depends on the vector of parameters , cost of replacing the engine, and the discount factor. Then the per-period utility is given by

where denotes the decision (keep or replace) and and represent the component of the utility observed by Harold Zurcher, but not John Rust. It is assumed that and are independent and identically distributed with Type I Extreme Value distribution, and that are independent of conditional on .

Then the optimal decisions satisfy the Bellman equation

where and are respectively transition densities for the observed and unobserved states variables. Time indices in the Bellman equation are dropped because the model is formulated in the infinite horizon settings, the unknown optimal policy is stationary, i.e. independent of time.

Given the distributional assumption on , the probability of particular choice is given by

where is a unique solution to the functional equation

It can be shown that the latter functional equation defines a contraction mapping if the state space is bounded, so there will be a unique solution for any , and further the implicit function theorem holds, so is also a smooth function of for each .

The Nested Fixed Point (NFXP) algorithm

File:NFXP.gif
NFXP estimator algorith

The contraction mapping above can be solved numerically for the fixed point that yields choice probabilities for any given value of . Log-likelihood function can then be formulated as

where and represent data on state variables (odometer readings) and decision (keep or replace) for individual buses, each in periods.

The joint algorithm for solving the fixed point problem given a particular value of parameter and maximizing the log-likelihood with respect to was named by John Rust nested fixed point algorithm (NFXP). Detailed Template:PDFlink is available along with the Gauss implementation.

Despite numerous contenders, the NFXP maximum likelihood estimator remains the leading estimation method for Markov decision models for nearly three decades now. [10]

Methodological debate

Although John Rust is a prominent structural econometrician, in the ongoing debate [11] between adepts of the structural and non-structural econometric approaches, he has expressed a balanced position. [12]

I really do not understand the widespread antipathy towards structural econometrics. I do not see any basis for the belief that the reduced form approaches adopted by statistical modelers is more justified or legitimate (or is less subjective) than the structural econometric approach adopted by economic modelers. Both types of modelers have to impose strong assumptions, and it seems all that we can say is that these models and the underlying identifying assumptions are just different.

It really isn’t productive to criticize the status quo in economics these days, nor is it productive to try to promote the virtues of structural estimation. Criticism only encourages the practitioners to rally around the flag. I think it is equally a waste of time to try to engage in salesmanship.

Instead, in his review of "The Limits of Inference without Theory" by Kenneth Wolpin [13] titled "The Limits of Inference with Theory" [14] John Rust brings attention to the limits of inference inherent to any econometric approach, and argues that collection of better data and closer cooperation between structural and the experimental economics will lead to more useful empirical knowledge.

My main message is though there is ample room for getting far more knowledge from limited data (and even more when we have access to “big data” ) by optimally combining inductive and deductive approaches to inference and learning, it is important to recognize that there are a number of inherent limits to inference that may be insuperable. These limits were not adequately addressed in Wolpin’s book, and motivated the title of this review.

John Rust holds a stronger position on the issue of disconnect between theoretical economics and econometrics from the real world (empirical) problems. At the "Causality in the Social Sciences Conference" held at Stanford University on December 5–6, 2014 he gave a talk titled "Template:PDFlink" [15] where he pointed out that development of complicated econometric theories is rewarded disproportionally to their practical usefulness.

Professional service

In 2004 John Rust co-founded the software development company Technoluddities, Inc. [16] which operates several web-based software products widely used by the economic profession. Technoluddities, Inc. owns trademarks to three of these services, namely Editorial Express, Conference Maker and Head Hunter. [17]

Editorial Express

Editorial Express is web-based editorial tracking software that can enable "paper-free" operation of the key editorial functions of a journal. Some of the features of this system include guaranteed low pricing, secure operations and data encryption, electronic submission of papers and referee reports, easy assignment of editors and referees, built-in email notification and automatic reminders, statistical functions and reporting. [18] Editorial express is regarded by many as one of the best journal management systems. [19]

Editorial Express used by many leading journals in economics including Econometrica, Quarterly Journal of Economics, RAND Journal of Economics, Review of Economic Studies Journal of Applied Econometrics, International Economic Review, Review of Economics and Statistics, Journal of Finance and other. [20]

Conference Maker

Conference Maker is web-based software for organizing international conferences. Conference Maker allows a program chair (or several co-chairs) and their selected program committee to handle the submission process in a decentralized fashion. All members of the program committee can log in at any time via secure password protected accounts and can view all submissions online. Program committee members are assigned certain subsets of submissions (usually designated by the person making the submission, unless overwritten by program committee members) and can make accept/reject decisions by clicking a button. There is also a simple interface for forming sessions, searching for discussants and session chairs, posting/updating the conference program to an automatically generated web page, and sending mass emails to arbitrarily selected subgroups of users.

Over 625 international conferences have used Conference Maker since it was introduced in 2001, more than 150,000 submissions have been made to Conference Maker for these various conferences and over 290,000 people worldwide have used it. [21]

Head Hunter

Head Hunter is web-based academic recruiting software specially designed as a "back end interface" to the EconJobMarket.org. Some of the features of this system include paperless operation, built-in scheduling module, easy setup, high security, electronic applications and reference letters. [22] Head Hunter is one of the internal interfaces (or "back ends") which facilitate for the departments the work with the applications and reference letters collected by EconJobMarket.org centralized application collection system.

EconJobMarket.org

EconJobMarket.org (EJM) is a nonprofit organization that facilitates the flow of information in the economics job market by providing a secure central repository for the files of job-market candidates (including papers, reference letters, and other materials) accessed on line. EJM was founded in 2007 by Martin Osborne, John Rust, and Joel Watson, and is run by a group of academic economists who volunteer their time and effort. [23] EconJobMarket.org is endorsed by The Econometric Society, Canadian Economics Association, European Economic Association, Eurasia Business and Economics Society, Society for Economic Dynamics, Verein für Socialpolitik, VOX and walras.org

The theoretical foundation for the creation of EconJobMarket.org is described in Chapter 7 of The Handbook of Market Design. [24]

EJM does not attempt to fundamentally alter the decentralized “endogenous search and matching” process by which the economics job market currently operates. Since there is unrestricted entry of intermediaries similar to EJM and a number of for-profit and non-profit organizations are currently competing in this market, we discuss the problem of market fragmentation that can occur when too many organizations attempt to intermediate trade in the market. Contrary to conventional wisdom in industrial organization theory, we show that unrestricted entry and competition of intermediaries can result in suboptimal outcomes. We discuss conditions under which the market might be improved if there is sufficient coordination to promote information sharing, such as establishing a dominant information clearinghouse that operates as a non-profit public service — a role EJM is trying to fulfill. [25]

EconJobMarket.org grew in various significant characteristics (number of job adds posted, number of recruiters' accounts, number of applicants' accounts, number of applications transmitted, number of recommenders' accounts, number of recommendations transmitted) between its inception and 2011 at an average annual rate between 79% and 194%. [26]

Selected publications

Solution and estimation of structural dynamic models

Market equilibrium, durable goods

Retirement and disability

Rental cars

Nuclear power plants

Philosophy of science

Books

  • Friedman, Daniel; Rust, John (1993). The double auction market: institutions, theories, and evidence. Vol. 14. Westview Press.

See also

References

  1. ^ "Fellows of Econometric Society". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  2. ^ "Awards of Econometric Society". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  3. ^ Aguirregabiria, Victor; Mira, Pedro (2010). "Dynamic discrete choice structural models: A survey". Journal of Econometrics. 156 (1). Elsevier: 38–67. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2009.09.007. Seminal papers include ... Rust(1987) on machine replacement.
  4. ^ "Citations of Rust(1994) on NFXP". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  5. ^ "Online research papers by John Rust". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  6. ^ Rust, John (1985). "Stationary equilibrium in a market for durable assets". Econometrica: 783–805. doi:10.2307/1912654.
  7. ^ Template:PDFlink
  8. ^ Template:PDFlink
  9. ^ Su, Che-Lin; Judd, Kenneth L. (2012). "Constrained Optimization Approaches to Estimation of Structural Models". Econometrica. 80 (5): 2213–2230. doi:10.3982/ECTA7925. ISSN 1468-0262.
  10. ^ Iskhakov, Fedor; Lee, Jinhyuk; Rust, John; Seo, Kyoungwon; Schjerning, Bertel (2014). "Constrained Optimization Approaches to Estimation of Structural Models: Comment". doi:10.2139/ssrn.2583655. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  11. ^ "Discussion of structural vs. reduced form approach at EconJobRumers.com anonymous professional forum". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  12. ^ Rust, John (2010). "Comments on: "Structural vs. atheoretic approaches to econometrics" by Michael Keane". Journal of Econometrics. 156 (1): 21–24. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2009.09.004. ISSN 0304-4076.
  13. ^ Wolpin, Kenneth I. (2013). The Limits of Inference without Theory. Tjalling C. Koopmans Memorial Lectures. The MIT Press.
  14. ^ Rust, John (2014). "The Limits of Inference with Theory: A Review of Wolpin (2013)". Journal of Economic Literature. 52 (3): 820–50. doi:10.1257/jel.52.3.820.
  15. ^ Template:PDFlink
  16. ^ "Maryland Corporates record of Technoluddities, Inc". Retrieved 22 May 2015. TECHNOLUDDITES, INC. is a company incorporated in Maryland and its company number is d10129625. TECHNOLUDDITES, INC. was registered on 07/30/2004
  17. ^ "Trademarks owned by Technoluddites, Inc". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  18. ^ "About Editorial Express". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  19. ^ Preston McAfee (May 2009). "Manuscript Central Software Review". Retrieved 22 May 2015. An editor asked me for my thoughts on Blackwell-Wiley's Manuscript Central, so I decided to put my thoughts out for everyone to see. I've used three programs to edit journals: Editorial Assistant, Editorial Express and Manuscript Central. I like Editorial Express the best, by a good margin.
  20. ^ "Journals using Editorial Express". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  21. ^ "About Conference Maker". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  22. ^ "About Head Hunter". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  23. ^ "EconJobMarket organizational structure". Retrieved 22 May 2015.
  24. ^ Vulkan, Nir; Roth, Alvin E; Neeman, Zvika, eds. (2013). The handbook of market design. OUP Oxford. ISBN 9780191668432.
  25. ^ Bandyopadhyay, Sarbartha; Iskhakov, Fedor; Johnson, Terence; Lee, Soohyung; McArthur, David; Rust, John; Watson, Joel; Watson, John (2013). "Can the Job Market for Economists Be Imptoved?". In Vulkan, Nir; Roth, Alvin E; Neeman, Zvika (eds.). The handbook of market design. OUP Oxford. ISBN 9780191668432.
  26. ^ Bandyopadhyay, Sarbartha; Iskhakov, Fedor; Johnson, Terence; Lee, Soohyung; McArthur, David; Rust, John; Watson, Joel; Watson, John (2013). "Can the Job Market for Economists Be Imptoved?". In Vulkan, Nir; Roth, Alvin E; Neeman, Zvika (eds.). The handbook of market design. OUP Oxford. ISBN 9780191668432.

External links