Property rights (economics): Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Restored revision 1014496059 by MrOllie (talk): Rv latest selfpromotion / citespam from COI editor
I attempted to format the article better and explain in a better way the ypes of property rights in relation to economics. I also tried to improve the coherency of the reasoning to have property rights and their general theory.
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Economics sidebar}}
{{Economics sidebar}}
'''Property rights''' are constructs in [[economics]] for determining how a resource or economic good is used and [[Ownership|owned]].<ref>{{cite web|last=Alchian|first=Armen A.|title=Property Rights|work=New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition (2008)|url= http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_P000226&edition=&field=keyword&q=private%20property%20rights&topicid=&result_number=2|quote= A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good.}}</ref> Resources can be owned by (and hence be the [[property]] of) individuals, associations, [[Collective ownership|collectives]], or governments.<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |last1=Alchian |first1=Armen A. |author-link1=Armen Alchian |editor=David R. Henderson |editor-link=David R. Henderson |encyclopedia=[[Concise Encyclopedia of Economics]] |title=Property Rights |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/PropertyRights.html |year=2008 |edition=2nd |publisher=[[Library of Economics and Liberty]] |location=Indianapolis |isbn=978-0-86597-665-8 |oclc=237794267 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070409065835/http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/PropertyRights.html |archive-date=2007-04-09 }}</ref> Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good. This attribute has three broad components<ref>• {{Cite news| title=Economics Glossary | url =http://www.coase.org/nieglossary.htm#Propertyrights | access-date = 2007-01-28 }}<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • {{Cite book|author=Thrainn Eggertsson |title=Economic behavior and institutions |publisher=Cambridge University Press |location=Cambridge, UK |year=1990 |isbn=978-0-521-34891-1 }}<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Dean Lueck (2008). "property law, economics and," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_E000219&edition=current&q=%20Property%20rights&topicid=&result_number=2 Abstract.]</ref> and is often referred to as a [[bundle of rights]]:<ref>Klein, Daniel B. and John Robinson. "Property: A Bundle of Rights? Prologue to the Symposium." ''Econ Journal Watch 8(3): 193–204'', September 2011.[http://econjwatch.org/issues/volume-8-issue-3-september-2011]</ref>
'''Property rights''' are constructs in [[economics]] for determining how a resource or economic good is used and [[Ownership|owned]].<ref>{{cite web|last=Alchian|first=Armen A.|title=Property Rights|work=New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition (2008)|url= http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_P000226&edition=&field=keyword&q=private%20property%20rights&topicid=&result_number=2|quote= A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good.}}</ref> Resources can be owned by (and hence be the [[property]] of) individuals, associations, [[Collective ownership|collectives]], or governments.<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |last1=Alchian |first1=Armen A. |author-link1=Armen Alchian |editor=David R. Henderson |editor-link=David R. Henderson |encyclopedia=[[Concise Encyclopedia of Economics]] |title=Property Rights |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/PropertyRights.html |year=2008 |edition=2nd |publisher=[[Library of Economics and Liberty]] |location=Indianapolis |isbn=978-0-86597-665-8 |oclc=237794267 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070409065835/http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/PropertyRights.html |archive-date=2007-04-09 }}</ref> Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good. This attribute has three broad components<ref>• {{Cite news| title=Economics Glossary | url =http://www.coase.org/nieglossary.htm#Propertyrights | access-date = 2007-01-28 }}<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • {{Cite book|author=Thrainn Eggertsson |title=Economic behavior and institutions |publisher=Cambridge University Press |location=Cambridge, UK |year=1990 |isbn=978-0-521-34891-1 }}<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Dean Lueck (2008). "property law, economics and," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_E000219&edition=current&q=%20Property%20rights&topicid=&result_number=2 Abstract.]</ref> and is often referred to as a [[bundle of rights]] in the United Staets:<ref>Klein, Daniel B. and John Robinson. "Property: A Bundle of Rights? Prologue to the Symposium." ''Econ Journal Watch 8(3): 193–204'', September 2011.[http://econjwatch.org/issues/volume-8-issue-3-september-2011]</ref>
# the right to use the good
# the right to use the good
# the right to earn income from the good
# the right to earn income from the good
# the right to transfer the good to others, alter it, abandon it, or destroy it (the right to ownership cessation)
# the right to transfer the good to others, alter it, abandon it, or destroy it (the right to ownership cessation)


== Conceptualizing Property in Economics Vs Law ==
== Regimes ==
The fields of economics and law do not have a general consensus on conceptions of property rights.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Cole|first=Daniel H.|last2=Grossman|first2=Peter Z.|date=2002-08-01|title=The Meaning of Property Rights: Law versus Economics?|url=http://le.uwpress.org/content/78/3/317|journal=Land Economics|language=en|volume=78|issue=3|pages=317–330|doi=10.2307/3146892|issn=0023-7639}}</ref> Various property types are used in law but the terminology can be seen in economic reports.<ref name="NZ" /> Sometimes in economics, property types are simply described as private or public/common in reference to [[Private good|private goods]] (excludable and rivalrous goods, like a phone)<ref name=":0">{{Citation|last=Alchian|first=Armen A.|title=Property Rights|date=2018|url=https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1814|work=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|pages=10892–10897|place=London|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK|language=en|doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1814|isbn=978-1-349-95189-5|access-date=2021-04-26}}</ref> and [[Public good (economics)|public goods]] (non-excludable and non-rivalrous goods, like air)<ref name=":1">{{Citation|last=Sandmo|first=Agnar|title=Public Goods|date=1989|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20215-7_26|work=Allocation, Information and Markets|pages=254–266|editor-last=Eatwell|editor-first=John|series=The New Palgrave|place=London|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK|language=en|doi=10.1007/978-1-349-20215-7_26|isbn=978-1-349-20215-7|access-date=2021-04-26|editor2-last=Milgate|editor2-first=Murray|editor3-last=Newman|editor3-first=Peter}}</ref> respectively.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Ostrom|first=Elinor|last2=Hess|first2=Charlotte|date=2007-11-29|title=Private and Common Property Rights|url=https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=1936062|language=en|location=Rochester, NY|doi=10.2139/ssrn.1936062}}</ref> Below is a list of the several property types defined and their relation to the economic concepts of [[excludability]] (the ability to limit the consumption of the good) and [[Rivalry (economics)|rivalry]] (a person's consumption of the good reduces the ability of another to consume it).
Property rights to a good must be defined, their use must be monitored, and possession of rights must be enforced.{{according to whom|date=September 2014}} The costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights are termed [[transaction costs]].<ref>{{Cite journal|title=Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets|journal=Journal of Law and Economics|date= April 1982|first=Yoram|last=Barzel|volume=25|issue=1|pages=27–48|doi=10.1086/467005|issn=0022-2186|jstor=725223}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|author=Douglas Allen |title=What are Transaction Costs? (Research in Law and Economics) |publisher=Jai Pr |year=1991 |isbn=978-0-7623-1115-6 }}</ref> Depending on the level of transaction costs, various forms of property rights institutions will develop. Each institutional form can be described by the distribution of rights.


=== Property Types ===
The following list is ordered from no property rights defined to all property rights being held by individuals<ref>{{Cite book|author=Daniel W. Bromley |title=Environment and Economy: Property Rights and Public Policy |publisher=Blackwell Pub |location=Cambridge, MA |year= 1991|isbn=978-1-55786-087-3 }}</ref>
* Nobodies property (''[[res nullius]]'') is not 'owned' by anyone. It is non-excludable (no one can exclude anyone else from using it), non-transferable, but may be [[rivalry (economics)|rival]] (one person's use of it reduces the quantity available to other users). Open-access property is not managed by anyone, and access to it is not controlled. There is no constraint on anyone using open-access property (excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly). Examples of currently open-access property is outer space or ocean fisheries (outside of territorial borders).
*Open-access property is owned by nobody(''[[res nullius]]''). It is non-excludable and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous. Open-access property is not managed by anyone, and access to it is not controlled. There is no constraint on anyone using open-access property (excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly). This is also known as a ''common property resource'' or a [[Common-pool resource|''common pool resources'']]'','' if rivalrous''.''<ref>{{Citation|last=Platteau|first=Jean-Philippe|title=Common Property Resources|date=2018|url=https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2085|work=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|pages=1868–1871|place=London|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK|language=en|doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2085|isbn=978-1-349-95189-5|access-date=2021-04-26}}</ref> [[Tragedy of the commons]] refers to this title. An example would be a If non-rivalrous, these are public goods; either impure (can be rivalrous on a large scale, for example, a road) or pure (cannot be rivalrous, no matter how much it is used, for example, the ocean (outside of territorial borders)).<ref name=":1" />


{{quote|text=Open-access property may exist because ownership has never been established, granted, by laws within a particular country, or because no effective controls are in place, or feasible, i.e., the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits. The government can sometimes effectively convert open access property into private, common, or public property through the land grant process, by legislating to define public/private rights previously not granted.|sign=Kevin Guerin|source=<ref name="NZ">Guerin, K. (2003). ''Property Rights and Environmental Policy: A New Zealand Perspective''. Wellington, New Zealand: NZ Treasury</ref>}}
{{quote|text=Open-access property may exist because ownership has never been established, granted, by laws within a particular country, or because no effective controls are in place, or feasible, i.e., the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits.|sign=|source=Encyclopedia of Law and Economics}}
* [[Public property]] (also known as [[state property]]) is property that is publicly owned, but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority. An example is a national park or a state-owned enterprise.<ref name="NZ"/>
*[[Public property]] (also known as [[state property]]) is non-excludable and rivalrous.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Snidal|first=Duncan|date=1979-12-01|title=Public Goods, Property Rights, and Political Organizations|url=https://doi.org/10.2307/2600328|journal=International Studies Quarterly|volume=23|issue=4|pages=532–566|doi=10.2307/2600328|issn=0020-8833}}</ref> This type of property is publicly owned, but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority. For example, a government pavement is non-excludable as anyone may use it but rivalrous as, the more people using it, the more likely it will be too crowded for another to join.<ref name="NZ" /> Public property is sometimes used interchangeably with ''public good,''<ref name=":2">{{Cite book|last=T.|first=Mahoney, Joseph|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/492090732|title=Economic foundations of strategy|date=2005|publisher=Sage|year=2005|isbn=1-4129-0542-7|oclc=492090732}}</ref> usually impure public goods.
* [[Private property]] is both excludable and rivalrous. Private property access, use, exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners.<ref name=":0" /> This is sometimes used interchangeably with private good.<ref name=":2" />
* Club Property is excludable but non-rival. This type of ownership is similar to public with the exception of excludability from individuals outside of the club.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Buchanan |first1=James M |title=An Economic Theory of Clubs |journal=Economica |date=1965 |volume=32 |issue=125 |pages=1–14}}</ref>
* [[Common property]] or collective property is property that is owned by a group of individuals. Access, use, and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners. Unlike open-access property, common property owners have greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement.<ref name="NZ" />
*[[Common property]] or collective property is excludable and rivalrous. Not to be confused with common property in reference to economics, this is in reference to law. It is property that is owned by a group of individuals. Access, use, and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners.<ref name="NZ" /> Unlike private property, common property has multiple owners which allows for a greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement. This would still be related to ''private goods''.
* [[Private property]] is both excludable and rival. Private property access, use, exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners.


=== Not Included in Property Types ===
== The environment ==
*[[Club good]] is excludable and non-rivalrous.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Buchanan|first1=James M|date=1965|title=An Economic Theory of Clubs|journal=Economica|volume=32|issue=125|pages=1–14}}</ref> For example, a streaming service such as Netflix is excludable due to the subscription fee but non-rivalrous as one person using Netflix does not affect the ability of another doing so. Law does not have a type of property in reference to this good.
Implicit or explicit property rights can be created by regulating the environment, either through prescriptive [[Command and control (government)|command and control]] approaches (e.g. limits on input/output/discharge quantities, specified processes/equipment, audits) or by [[market-based instruments]] (e.g. taxes, transferable permits or quotas),<ref name="NZ" /> and more recently through cooperative, self-regulatory, post-regulatory and reflexive law approaches.<ref>See literature on post-regulatory approaches and reflexive law, especially literature from Gunther Teubner. See also the example of the 'conservation property right'</ref> See the [[Conservation Property Right]]


== Property Rights Theory ==
It has been proposed by [[Ronald Coase]] that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and relying on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future. At common law nuisance and tort law allows adjacent property holders to seek compensation when individual actions diminish the air and water quality for adjacent landowners.
Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits, that owners will have perfect information, that scale economies are manageable, transaction costs are bearable, and that legal frameworks operate efficiently.<ref name="NZ" />


== Literature ==
=== Introduction ===
Property rights theory is an exploration of how providing [[Stakeholder theory|stakeholders]] with ownership of any [[factors of production]], not just land, will increase the efficiency of an economy as the gains from providing the rights exceed the costs.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Demsetz|first=Harold|date=1967|title=“Toward a Theory of Property Rights.”|url=https://econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/Ec100C/Readings/Demsetz_Property_Rights.pdf|journal=The American Economic Review|volume=57|pages=347-359}}</ref> Implicit or explicit property rights can be created through government regulation in the market, either through prescriptive [[Command and control (government)|command and control]] approaches (e.g. limits on input/output/discharge quantities, specified processes/equipment, audits) or by [[market-based instruments]] (e.g. taxes, transferable permits or quotas),<ref name="NZ" /> and more recently through cooperative, self-regulatory, post-regulatory and reflexive law approaches.<ref>See literature on post-regulatory approaches and reflexive law, especially literature from Gunther Teubner. See also the example of the 'conservation property right'</ref>
In 2013 researchers<ref>Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler-Vidra, October 2012, Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights, Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services (EPS PEAKS)https://partnerplatform.org/?tcafmd80</ref> produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes: (a) reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest, and (b) improvements in household welfare; the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries. They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes, including better management of natural resources.


It has been proposed by [[Ronald Coase]] that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and relying on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Coase|first=R. H.|date=1960-10-XX|title=The Problem of Social Cost|url=https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/466560|journal=The Journal of Law and Economics|language=en|volume=3|pages=1–44|doi=10.1086/466560|issn=0022-2186}}</ref> This video provides examples of why enforcing property rights is more efficient for the market than not doing so https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=AJy7pWK0W8g&ab_channel=KhanAcademy<ref>{{Citation|title=Property rights in a market system {{!}} Basic Economic Concepts {{!}} AP(R) Microeconomics {{!}} Khan Academy|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=AJy7pWK0W8g|language=en|access-date=2021-04-26}}</ref>. Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits, that owners will have perfect information, that [[Economies of scale|scale economies]] are manageable, [[Transaction cost|transaction costs]] are bearable, and that legal frameworks operate efficiently.<ref name="NZ" />
Despite the overwhelming evidence on the economic relevance of property rights, economists have only recently started studying their determinants by looking at the trade-off between the dispersed coercive power in a state of anarchy and the predation by a central authority. To illustrate, incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions. When instead, the state is entrusted the power to protect property, it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Handbook of Development Economics|last=Besley, Timothy|first=and Maitreesh Ghatak|publisher=Elsevier|year=2010|location=Amsterdam|pages=4525–4595}}</ref> The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship, originated from the seminal contribution by [[Guido Calabresi]] and [[Douglas Melamed]].<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Calabresi, Guido|first=and Melamed, A. Douglas|date=1972|title=Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral|url=https://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/fss_papers/1983|journal=Harvard Law Review |volume=85 |issue=6|pages=1089–1128|doi=10.2307/1340059|jstor=1340059}}</ref> These authors argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade, legalized private expropriation in the form of, for instance, liability rules can be welfare-increasing. To elaborate, when property is fully protected, some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs. When the protection of property is weak instead, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. Hence, a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers' valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low-valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights. Crucially, this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions. These data measure “horizontal property rights” and thus the extent of protection of property from “direct and indirect private takings,” which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites, which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature. To capture preference diversity, the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity, which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations, such as preferences.<ref>{{Cite book|title=The History and Geography of Human Genes|last=Cavalli-Sforza, Luca L.|first=Paolo Menozzi, and Alberto Piazza|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=1994|location=Princeton, NJ}}</ref> Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners' property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest. Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal.


In economics, depending on the level of transaction costs, various forms of property rights institutions will develop.<ref name=":2" /> In economics, an [[Institutional economics|institution]] is
== Property rights approach to the theory of the firm ==
The property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the [[Incomplete contracts|incomplete contracting]] paradigm was developed by [[Sanford J. Grossman|Sanford Grossman]], [[Oliver Hart (economist)|Oliver Hart]], and [[John Hardman Moore|John Moore]].<ref>{{Cite journal|title = The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration|journal = Journal of Political Economy|date = 1986|issn = 0022-3808|pages = 691–719|volume = 94|issue = 4|doi = 10.1086/261404|first = Sanford J.|last = Grossman|first2 = Oliver D.|last2 = Hart|hdl = 1721.1/63378|url = http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:3450060}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm|journal = Journal of Political Economy|date = 1990|issn = 0022-3808|pages = 1119–1158|volume = 98|issue = 6|doi = 10.1086/261729|first = Oliver|last = Hart|first2 = John|last2 = Moore|citeseerx = 10.1.1.472.9089}}</ref> These authors argue that in the real world, contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world. There will be renegotiations in the future, so parties have insufficient investment incentives (since they will only get a fraction of the investment's return in future negotiations); i.e., there is a [[hold-up problem]]. Hence, property rights matter, because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached. In other words, property rights determine the parties' future bargaining positions (while their bargaining powers, i.e. their fractions of the renegotiation surplus, are independent of the property rights allocation).<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach|journal = Economics Letters|date = 2013|pages = 28–31|volume = 119|issue = 1|doi = 10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.011|first = Patrick W.|last = Schmitz|url = https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/44953/1/MPRA_paper_44953.pdf}}</ref> The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms. Yet, it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization.<ref>{{Cite journal|title = The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons|url = http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/112/4/1127|journal = The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date = 1997|issn = 0033-5533|pages = 1127–1161|volume = 112|issue = 4|doi = 10.1162/003355300555448|language = en|first = Oliver|last = Hart|first2 = Andrei|last2 = Shleifer|first3 = Robert W.|last3 = Vishny}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks|journal = Journal of Public Economics|date = 2010|pages = 258–268|volume = 94|issue = 3–4|doi = 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009|first = Eva I.|last = Hoppe|first2 = Patrick W.|last2 = Schmitz}}</ref> The property rights approach has been extended in many directions. For instance, some authors have studied different bargaining solutions,<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers? Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm|url = http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/113/2/361|journal = The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date = 1998|issn = 0033-5533|pages = 361–386|volume = 113|issue = 2|doi = 10.1162/003355398555621|language = en|first = David de|last = Meza|first2 = Ben|last2 = Lockwood}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Noncooperative Bargaining, Hostages, and Optimal Asset Ownership|jstor = 117010|journal = The American Economic Review|date = 1998|pages = 882–901|volume = 88|issue = 4|first = Y. Stephen|last = Chiu}}</ref> while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information.<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Information Gathering, Transaction Costs, and the Property Rights Approach|journal = American Economic Review|pages = 422–434|volume = 96|issue = 1|doi = 10.1257/000282806776157722|first = Patrick W|last = Schmitz|date = 2006}}</ref>


{{Quote|text="a complex of positions, roles, norms and values lodged in particular types of social structures and organising relatively stable patterns of human activity with respect to fundamental problems in producing life-sustaining resources, in reproducing individuals, and in sustaining viable societal structures within a given environment."|author=Johnathon Turner|title=The Institutional Order}}
== Role of property rights in economic and political development ==
Classical economists such as [[Adam Smith]] and [[Karl Marx]] generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development, and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition.<ref>{{Cite journal|last= Besley|first= Timothy|last2= Maitreesh|first2= Ghatak|date= 2009|editor-last= Rodrik|editor-first= Dani|editor2-last= Rosenzweig|editor2-first= Mark R|title= Property Rights and Economic Development|journal= Handbook of Development Economics|volume= V|pages= 4526–28}}</ref> A widely accepted explanation is that well-enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities, such as investment, innovation and trade, which lead to a more efficient market.<ref>{{Cite journal|last= Acemoglu|first= Daron|last2= Johnson|first2= Simon|last3= Robinson|first3= James|date= 2005|title= Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth|journal= Handbook of Economic Growth|volume= 1|pages= 397}}</ref> The development of property rights in Europe during the Middle Ages provides an example.<ref>{{Cite book|last= Acemoglu|first= Daron|last2= Johnson|first2= Simon|last3= Robinson|first3= James A.|date= 2005|title= Chapter 6 Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth|doi= 10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01006-3|volume= 1|pages= 385–472|series= Handbook of Economic Growth|isbn= 978-0-444-52041-8}}</ref> During this epoch, full political power came into the hands of hereditary monarchies, which often abused their power to exploit producers, to impose arbitrary taxes, or to refuse to pay their debts. The lack of protection for property rights provided little incentive for landowners and merchants to invest in land, physical or human capital, or technology. After the [[First English Civil War|English Civil War]] of 1642-1646 and the [[Glorious Revolution]] of 1688, shifts of political power away from the Stuart monarchs led to the strengthening of property rights of both land and capital owners. Consequently, rapid economic development took place, setting the stage for [[Industrial Revolution]].


For specificity in the case of economic property rights, this is a system or structure that has value and stability. [[Transaction costs]] are the costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Barzel|first=Yoram|date=April 1982|title=Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets|journal=Journal of Law and Economics|volume=25|issue=1|pages=27–48|doi=10.1086/467005|issn=0022-2186|jstor=725223}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|author=Douglas Allen|title=What are Transaction Costs? (Research in Law and Economics)|publisher=Jai Pr|year=1991|isbn=978-0-7623-1115-6}}</ref> Each institutional form can be described by the distribution of rights.
As an economy develops, the need for property rights increases. This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else. So as a nation grows the necessity for a well-defined property rights grows as well.<ref>Alchian, Armen A (1965). "Some Economics of Property Rights". II Politico. 30 (4): 816–829.</ref> Additionally, property rights are foundational for a capitalist system, allowing for growth and wealth creation.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Demsetz |first1=Harold |title=Toward a Theory of Property Rights |journal=American Economic Association |date=1967 |volume=57 |pages=347–359}}</ref>


=== Benefits of Implementing Property Rights<ref>{{Cite web|date=2020-01-17|title=Property rights {{!}} Economics Online {{!}} Economics Online|url=https://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Market_failures/Property_rights.html|access-date=2021-04-26|language=en-US}}</ref> <ref>{{Cite book|last=Yoram.|first=Barzel,|url=http://worldcat.org/oclc/863296486|title=Economic analysis of property rights|date=1997|publisher=Cambridge University Press|year=1997|isbn=0-521-59275-5|oclc=863296486}}</ref><ref>{{Citation|title=Concluding remarks|date=1990|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/contracting-for-property-rights/concluding-remarks/4BEEE531103D3A908548FE2BDF97250F|work=Contracting for Property Rights|pages=115–121|editor-last=Libecap|editor-first=Gary D.|series=Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions|place=Cambridge|publisher=Cambridge University Press|doi=10.1017/cbo9780511664120.008|isbn=978-0-521-44904-5|access-date=2021-04-26}}</ref> ===
Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources.<ref>{{Cite journal|last= Alchian|first= Armen|last2= Demsetz|first2= Harold|date= 1973|title= The Property Right Paradigm|url= https://semanticscholar.org/paper/3d31eaa5fddc8507fdbe238ceca495daa3d6d242|journal= The Journal of Economic History|volume= 33|issue= 1|pages= 16–27|doi= 10.1017/S0022050700076403}}</ref> Empirically, using historical data of former European colonies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions – those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity – lead to economic prosperity.<ref>{{Cite book|last= Acemoglu|first= Daron|last2= Johnson|first2= Simon|last3= Robinson|first3= James|date= 2005|chapter= Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth|chapter-url= https://books.google.com/books?id=fQ4JBwLsz8cC|title= Handbook of Economic Growth|volume= 1|pages= 385–472}}</ref>
Opportunism is discouraged as it is harder to exploit a good protected by enforced property rights. For example, a song can be easily pirated from purchased copies and, with no punishment, this form of the [[free-rider problem]] likely occurs. This causes the [[price mechanism]] to be less effective at finding the true market equilibrium and hurts the owners of the good who did not get it through opportunism.


The [[moral hazard]] is less likely to influence the actions of consumers, meaning they will be less likely to exploit resources unsustainably or inefficiently as property is protected. This will lead to a lower group cost overall as people will not be able to exploit these resources as easily, causing less inefficiency issues.
Property rights might be closely related to the evolution of political order, due to their protections of an individual's claims on economic rents.{{citation needed|date=August 2018}} North, Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites' rent-seeking activities. Particularly, the legal and political systems that protect elites' claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so-called "limited access order", in which non-elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges.<ref>{{Cite journal|last= North|first= Douglass C|last2= Wallis|first2= John J|last3= Weingast|first3= Barry R|date= 2006|title= A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history|journal= National Bureau of Economic Research|volume= 12795|pages= 32–33}}</ref> In a historical study of medieval England, for instance, North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites' interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century.<ref>{{Cite journal|last= North|first= Douglass C|last2= Thomas|first2= Robert P|date= 1971|title= The Rise and Fall of the Manorial System: A Theoretical Model|journal= The Journal of Economic History|volume= 31|issue= 4|pages= 777–803|doi= 10.1017/S0022050700074623}}</ref> In contrast, the modern "open access order", which consists of a democratic political system and a free- market economy, usually features widespread, secure and impersonal property rights. Universal property rights, along with impersonal economic and political competition, downplay the role of rent-seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy.<ref>

{{Cite journal
=== Real-world Applications and Political Interconnection ===
|last= North|first= Douglass C
Classical economists such as [[Adam Smith]] and [[Karl Marx]] generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development, and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Besley|first=Timothy|last2=Maitreesh|first2=Ghatak|date=2009|editor-last=Rodrik|editor-first=Dani|editor2-last=Rosenzweig|editor2-first=Mark R|title=Property Rights and Economic Development|journal=Handbook of Development Economics|volume=V|pages=4526–28}}</ref> A widely accepted explanation is that well-enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities, such as investment, innovation and trade, which lead to a more efficient market.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Acemoglu|first=Daron|last2=Johnson|first2=Simon|last3=Robinson|first3=James|date=2005|title=Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth|journal=Handbook of Economic Growth|volume=1|pages=397}}</ref> The development of property rights in Europe during the Middle Ages provides an example.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Acemoglu|first=Daron|title=Chapter 6 Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth|last2=Johnson|first2=Simon|last3=Robinson|first3=James A.|date=2005|isbn=978-0-444-52041-8|series=Handbook of Economic Growth|volume=1|pages=385–472|doi=10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01006-3}}</ref> During this epoch, full political power came into the hands of hereditary monarchies, which often abused their power to exploit producers, to impose arbitrary taxes, or to refuse to pay their debts. The lack of protection for property rights provided little incentive for landowners and merchants to invest in land, physical or human capital, or technology. After the [[First English Civil War|English Civil War]] of 1642-1646 and the [[Glorious Revolution]] of 1688, shifts of political power away from the Stuart monarchs led to the strengthening of property rights of both land and capital owners. Consequently, rapid economic development took place, setting the stage for [[Industrial Revolution]].
|last2= Wallis|first2= John J

|last3= Weingast|first3= Barry R|date= 2009
As an economy develops, the need for property rights increases. This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else. So as a nation grows the necessity for a well-defined property rights grows as well.<ref>Alchian, Armen A (1965). "Some Economics of Property Rights". II Politico. 30 (4): 816–829.</ref> Additionally, property rights are foundational for a capitalist system, allowing for growth and wealth creation.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Demsetz|first1=Harold|date=1967|title=Toward a Theory of Property Rights|journal=American Economic Association|volume=57|pages=347–359}}</ref>
|title= Violence and the Rise of Open-Access Orders

|journal= Journal of Democracy
Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Alchian|first=Armen|last2=Demsetz|first2=Harold|date=1973|title=The Property Right Paradigm|url=https://semanticscholar.org/paper/3d31eaa5fddc8507fdbe238ceca495daa3d6d242|journal=The Journal of Economic History|volume=33|issue=1|pages=16–27|doi=10.1017/S0022050700076403}}</ref> Empirically, using historical data of former European colonies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions – those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity – lead to economic prosperity.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Acemoglu|first=Daron|title=Handbook of Economic Growth|last2=Johnson|first2=Simon|last3=Robinson|first3=James|date=2005|volume=1|pages=385–472|chapter=Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fQ4JBwLsz8cC}}</ref>
|volume= 20|issue= 1|pages= 55–68

|doi= 10.1353/jod.0.0060
North, Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites' rent-seeking activities. Particularly, the legal and political systems that protect elites' claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so-called "limited access order", in which non-elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=North|first=Douglass C|last2=Wallis|first2=John J|last3=Weingast|first3=Barry R|date=2006|title=A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history|journal=National Bureau of Economic Research|volume=12795|pages=32–33}}</ref> In a historical study of medieval England, for instance, North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites' interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=North|first=Douglass C|last2=Thomas|first2=Robert P|date=1971|title=The Rise and Fall of the Manorial System: A Theoretical Model|journal=The Journal of Economic History|volume=31|issue=4|pages=777–803|doi=10.1017/S0022050700074623}}</ref> In contrast, the modern "open access order", which consists of a democratic political system and a free- market economy, usually features widespread, secure and impersonal property rights. Universal property rights, along with impersonal economic and political competition, downplay the role of rent-seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy.<ref>
}}
{{Cite journal|last=North|first=Douglass C|last2=Wallis|first2=John J|last3=Weingast|first3=Barry R|date=2009|title=Violence and the Rise of Open-Access Orders|journal=Journal of Democracy|volume=20|issue=1|pages=55–68|doi=10.1353/jod.0.0060}}
</ref>
</ref>

== Property rights approach to the theory of the firm ==
The property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the [[Incomplete contracts|incomplete contracting]] paradigm was developed by [[Sanford J. Grossman|Sanford Grossman]], [[Oliver Hart (economist)|Oliver Hart]], and [[John Hardman Moore|John Moore]].<ref>{{Cite journal|title = The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration|journal = Journal of Political Economy|date = 1986|issn = 0022-3808|pages = 691–719|volume = 94|issue = 4|doi = 10.1086/261404|first = Sanford J.|last = Grossman|first2 = Oliver D.|last2 = Hart|hdl = 1721.1/63378|url = http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:3450060}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm|journal = Journal of Political Economy|date = 1990|issn = 0022-3808|pages = 1119–1158|volume = 98|issue = 6|doi = 10.1086/261729|first = Oliver|last = Hart|first2 = John|last2 = Moore|citeseerx = 10.1.1.472.9089}}</ref> These authors argue that in the real world, contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world. There will be renegotiations in the future, so parties have insufficient investment incentives (since they will only get a fraction of the investment's return in future negotiations); i.e., there is a [[hold-up problem]]. Hence, property rights matter, because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached. In other words, property rights determine the parties' future bargaining positions (while their bargaining powers, i.e. their fractions of the renegotiation surplus, are independent of the property rights allocation).<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach|journal = Economics Letters|date = 2013|pages = 28–31|volume = 119|issue = 1|doi = 10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.011|first = Patrick W.|last = Schmitz|url = https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/44953/1/MPRA_paper_44953.pdf}}</ref> The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms. Yet, it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization.<ref>{{Cite journal|title = The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons|url = http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/112/4/1127|journal = The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date = 1997|issn = 0033-5533|pages = 1127–1161|volume = 112|issue = 4|doi = 10.1162/003355300555448|language = en|first = Oliver|last = Hart|first2 = Andrei|last2 = Shleifer|first3 = Robert W.|last3 = Vishny}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks|journal = Journal of Public Economics|date = 2010|pages = 258–268|volume = 94|issue = 3–4|doi = 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009|first = Eva I.|last = Hoppe|first2 = Patrick W.|last2 = Schmitz}}</ref> The property rights approach has been extended in many directions. For instance, some authors have studied different bargaining solutions,<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers? Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm|url = http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/113/2/361|journal = The Quarterly Journal of Economics|date = 1998|issn = 0033-5533|pages = 361–386|volume = 113|issue = 2|doi = 10.1162/003355398555621|language = en|first = David de|last = Meza|first2 = Ben|last2 = Lockwood}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|title = Noncooperative Bargaining, Hostages, and Optimal Asset Ownership|jstor = 117010|journal = The American Economic Review|date = 1998|pages = 882–901|volume = 88|issue = 4|first = Y. Stephen|last = Chiu}}</ref> while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information.<ref>{{Cite journal|title = Information Gathering, Transaction Costs, and the Property Rights Approach|journal = American Economic Review|pages = 422–434|volume = 96|issue = 1|doi = 10.1257/000282806776157722|first = Patrick W|last = Schmitz|date = 2006}}</ref>

== Further Literature ==
In 2013, researchers<ref>Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler-Vidra, October 2012, Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights, Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services (EPS PEAKS)https://partnerplatform.org/?tcafmd80</ref> produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes: (a) reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest, and (b) improvements in household welfare; the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries. They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes, including better management of natural resources.

Despite the overwhelming evidence on the economic relevance of property rights, economists have only recently started studying their determinants by looking at the trade-off between the dispersed coercive power in a state of anarchy and the predation by a central authority. To illustrate, incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions. When instead, the state is entrusted the power to protect property, it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Besley, Timothy|first=and Maitreesh Ghatak|title=Handbook of Development Economics|publisher=Elsevier|year=2010|location=Amsterdam|pages=4525–4595}}</ref> The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship, originated from the seminal contribution by [[Guido Calabresi]] and [[Douglas Melamed]].<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Calabresi, Guido|first=and Melamed, A. Douglas|date=1972|title=Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral|url=https://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/fss_papers/1983|journal=Harvard Law Review|volume=85|issue=6|pages=1089–1128|doi=10.2307/1340059|jstor=1340059}}</ref> These authors argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade, legalized private expropriation in the form of, for instance, liability rules can be welfare-increasing. To elaborate, when property is fully protected, some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs. When the protection of property is weak instead, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. Hence, a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers' valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low-valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights. Crucially, this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions. These data measure “horizontal property rights” and thus the extent of protection of property from “direct and indirect private takings,” which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites, which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature. To capture preference diversity, the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity, which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations, such as preferences.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Cavalli-Sforza, Luca L.|first=Paolo Menozzi, and Alberto Piazza|title=The History and Geography of Human Genes|publisher=Princeton University Press|year=1994|location=Princeton, NJ}}</ref> Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners' property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest. Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal.


== See also ==
== See also ==
Line 75: Line 81:


== References ==
== References ==
<references />
{{Reflist|30em}}

{{Property navbox|state=expanded}}
{{Property navbox|state=expanded}}
{{Environmental social science}}
{{Environmental social science}}

Revision as of 05:59, 26 April 2021

Property rights are constructs in economics for determining how a resource or economic good is used and owned.[1] Resources can be owned by (and hence be the property of) individuals, associations, collectives, or governments.[2] Property rights can be viewed as an attribute of an economic good. This attribute has three broad components[3] and is often referred to as a bundle of rights in the United Staets:[4]

  1. the right to use the good
  2. the right to earn income from the good
  3. the right to transfer the good to others, alter it, abandon it, or destroy it (the right to ownership cessation)

Conceptualizing Property in Economics Vs Law

The fields of economics and law do not have a general consensus on conceptions of property rights.[5] Various property types are used in law but the terminology can be seen in economic reports.[6] Sometimes in economics, property types are simply described as private or public/common in reference to private goods (excludable and rivalrous goods, like a phone)[7] and public goods (non-excludable and non-rivalrous goods, like air)[8] respectively.[9] Below is a list of the several property types defined and their relation to the economic concepts of excludability (the ability to limit the consumption of the good) and rivalry (a person's consumption of the good reduces the ability of another to consume it).

Property Types

  • Open-access property is owned by nobody(res nullius). It is non-excludable and can be rivalrous or non-rivalrous. Open-access property is not managed by anyone, and access to it is not controlled. There is no constraint on anyone using open-access property (excluding people is either impossible or prohibitively costly). This is also known as a common property resource or a common pool resources, if rivalrous.[10] Tragedy of the commons refers to this title. An example would be a If non-rivalrous, these are public goods; either impure (can be rivalrous on a large scale, for example, a road) or pure (cannot be rivalrous, no matter how much it is used, for example, the ocean (outside of territorial borders)).[8]

Open-access property may exist because ownership has never been established, granted, by laws within a particular country, or because no effective controls are in place, or feasible, i.e., the cost of exclusivity outweighs the benefits.

— Encyclopedia of Law and Economics
  • Public property (also known as state property) is non-excludable and rivalrous.[11] This type of property is publicly owned, but its access and use are managed and controlled by a government agency or organization granted such authority. For example, a government pavement is non-excludable as anyone may use it but rivalrous as, the more people using it, the more likely it will be too crowded for another to join.[6] Public property is sometimes used interchangeably with public good,[12] usually impure public goods.
  • Private property is both excludable and rivalrous. Private property access, use, exclusion and management are controlled by the private owner or a group of legal owners.[7] This is sometimes used interchangeably with private good.[12]
  • Common property or collective property is excludable and rivalrous. Not to be confused with common property in reference to economics, this is in reference to law. It is property that is owned by a group of individuals. Access, use, and exclusion are controlled by the joint owners.[6] Unlike private property, common property has multiple owners which allows for a greater ability to manage conflicts through shared benefits and enforcement. This would still be related to private goods.

Not Included in Property Types

  • Club good is excludable and non-rivalrous.[13] For example, a streaming service such as Netflix is excludable due to the subscription fee but non-rivalrous as one person using Netflix does not affect the ability of another doing so. Law does not have a type of property in reference to this good.

Property Rights Theory

Introduction

Property rights theory is an exploration of how providing stakeholders with ownership of any factors of production, not just land, will increase the efficiency of an economy as the gains from providing the rights exceed the costs.[14] Implicit or explicit property rights can be created through government regulation in the market, either through prescriptive command and control approaches (e.g. limits on input/output/discharge quantities, specified processes/equipment, audits) or by market-based instruments (e.g. taxes, transferable permits or quotas),[6] and more recently through cooperative, self-regulatory, post-regulatory and reflexive law approaches.[15]

It has been proposed by Ronald Coase that clearly defining and assigning property rights would resolve environmental problems by internalizing externalities and relying on incentives of private owners to conserve resources for the future.[16] This video provides examples of why enforcing property rights is more efficient for the market than not doing so https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=AJy7pWK0W8g&ab_channel=KhanAcademy[17]. Critics of this view argue that this assumes that it is possible to internalize all environmental benefits, that owners will have perfect information, that scale economies are manageable, transaction costs are bearable, and that legal frameworks operate efficiently.[6]

In economics, depending on the level of transaction costs, various forms of property rights institutions will develop.[12] In economics, an institution is

"a complex of positions, roles, norms and values lodged in particular types of social structures and organising relatively stable patterns of human activity with respect to fundamental problems in producing life-sustaining resources, in reproducing individuals, and in sustaining viable societal structures within a given environment."

— Johnathon Turner, The Institutional Order

For specificity in the case of economic property rights, this is a system or structure that has value and stability. Transaction costs are the costs of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights.[18][19] Each institutional form can be described by the distribution of rights.

Benefits of Implementing Property Rights[20] [21][22]

Opportunism is discouraged as it is harder to exploit a good protected by enforced property rights. For example, a song can be easily pirated from purchased copies and, with no punishment, this form of the free-rider problem likely occurs. This causes the price mechanism to be less effective at finding the true market equilibrium and hurts the owners of the good who did not get it through opportunism.

The moral hazard is less likely to influence the actions of consumers, meaning they will be less likely to exploit resources unsustainably or inefficiently as property is protected. This will lead to a lower group cost overall as people will not be able to exploit these resources as easily, causing less inefficiency issues.

Real-world Applications and Political Interconnection

Classical economists such as Adam Smith and Karl Marx generally recognize the importance of property rights in the process of economic development, and modern mainstream economics agree with such a recognition.[23] A widely accepted explanation is that well-enforced property rights provide incentives for individuals to participate in economic activities, such as investment, innovation and trade, which lead to a more efficient market.[24] The development of property rights in Europe during the Middle Ages provides an example.[25] During this epoch, full political power came into the hands of hereditary monarchies, which often abused their power to exploit producers, to impose arbitrary taxes, or to refuse to pay their debts. The lack of protection for property rights provided little incentive for landowners and merchants to invest in land, physical or human capital, or technology. After the English Civil War of 1642-1646 and the Glorious Revolution of 1688, shifts of political power away from the Stuart monarchs led to the strengthening of property rights of both land and capital owners. Consequently, rapid economic development took place, setting the stage for Industrial Revolution.

As an economy develops, the need for property rights increases. This is due to the underlying assumption that within property rights other people must be present in order to have the rights over somebody else. So as a nation grows the necessity for a well-defined property rights grows as well.[26] Additionally, property rights are foundational for a capitalist system, allowing for growth and wealth creation.[27]

Property rights are also believed to lower transaction costs by providing an efficient resolution for conflicts over scarce resources.[28] Empirically, using historical data of former European colonies, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson find substantial evidence that good economic institutions – those that provide secure property rights and equality of opportunity – lead to economic prosperity.[29]

North, Wallis and Weingast argue that property rights originate to facilitate elites' rent-seeking activities. Particularly, the legal and political systems that protect elites' claims on rent revenues form the basis of the so-called "limited access order", in which non-elites are denied access to political power and economic privileges.[30] In a historical study of medieval England, for instance, North and Thomas find that the dramatic development of English land laws in the 13th century resulted from elites' interests in exploiting rent revenues from land ownership after a sudden rise in land price in the 12th century.[31] In contrast, the modern "open access order", which consists of a democratic political system and a free- market economy, usually features widespread, secure and impersonal property rights. Universal property rights, along with impersonal economic and political competition, downplay the role of rent-seeking and instead favor innovations and productive activities in a modern economy.[32]

Property rights approach to the theory of the firm

The property rights approach to the theory of the firm based on the incomplete contracting paradigm was developed by Sanford Grossman, Oliver Hart, and John Moore.[33][34] These authors argue that in the real world, contracts are incomplete and hence it is impossible to contractually specify what decisions will have to be taken in any conceivable state of the world. There will be renegotiations in the future, so parties have insufficient investment incentives (since they will only get a fraction of the investment's return in future negotiations); i.e., there is a hold-up problem. Hence, property rights matter, because they determine who has control over future decisions if no agreement will be reached. In other words, property rights determine the parties' future bargaining positions (while their bargaining powers, i.e. their fractions of the renegotiation surplus, are independent of the property rights allocation).[35] The property rights approach to the theory of the firm can thus explain pros and cons of integration in the context of private firms. Yet, it has also been applied in various other frameworks such as public good provision and privatization.[36][37] The property rights approach has been extended in many directions. For instance, some authors have studied different bargaining solutions,[38][39] while other authors have studied the role of asymmetric information.[40]

Further Literature

In 2013, researchers[41] produced an annotated bibliography on the property rights literature concerned with two principal outcomes: (a) reduction in investors risk and increase in incentives to invest, and (b) improvements in household welfare; the researchers explored the channels through which property rights affect growth and household welfare in developing countries. They found that better protection of property rights can affect several development outcomes, including better management of natural resources.

Despite the overwhelming evidence on the economic relevance of property rights, economists have only recently started studying their determinants by looking at the trade-off between the dispersed coercive power in a state of anarchy and the predation by a central authority. To illustrate, incomplete property rights allow agents with valuation lower than that of the original owners of economic value to inefficiently expropriate them distorting in this way their investment and effort exertion decisions. When instead, the state is entrusted the power to protect property, it might directly expropriate private parties if not sufficiently constrained by an efficient political process.[42] The necessity of strong protection of property for efficiency has been however criticized by a vast legal scholarship, originated from the seminal contribution by Guido Calabresi and Douglas Melamed.[43] These authors argue that in the face of transaction costs sufficiently sizeable to prevent consensual trade, legalized private expropriation in the form of, for instance, liability rules can be welfare-increasing. To elaborate, when property is fully protected, some agents with valuation higher than that of the original owners will be unable to legally acquire value because of sizable transaction costs. When the protection of property is weak instead, low-valuation potential buyers inefficiently expropriate original owners. Hence, a rise in the heterogeneity of the potential buyers' valuations makes inefficient expropriation by low-valuation potential buyers be more important from a social welfare point of view than inefficient exclusion from trade and so induces stronger property rights. Crucially, this prediction survives even after considering production and investment activities and it is consistent with a novel dataset on the rules on the acquisition of ownership through adverse possession and on the use of government takings to transfer real property from a private party to another private party prevailing in 126 jurisdictions. These data measure “horizontal property rights” and thus the extent of protection of property from “direct and indirect private takings,” which are ubiquitous forms of expropriation that occur daily within the rule of law and are thus different from predation by the state and the elites, which is much less common but has been the focus of the economics literature. To capture preference diversity, the author uses the contemporary genetic diversity, which is a primitive metric of the genealogical distance between populations with a common ancestor and so of the differences in characteristics transmitted across generations, such as preferences.[44] Regression analysis reveals that the protection of the original owners' property rights is the strongest where contemporary genetic diversity is the largest. Evidence from several different identification strategies suggests that this relationship is indeed causal.

See also

References

  1. ^ Alchian, Armen A. "Property Rights". New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition (2008). A property right is a socially enforced right to select uses of an economic good.
  2. ^ Alchian, Armen A. (2008). "Property Rights". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0-86597-665-8. OCLC 237794267. Archived from the original on 2007-04-09.
  3. ^ "Economics Glossary". Retrieved 2007-01-28.
       • Thrainn Eggertsson (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-34891-1.
       • Dean Lueck (2008). "property law, economics and," The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  4. ^ Klein, Daniel B. and John Robinson. "Property: A Bundle of Rights? Prologue to the Symposium." Econ Journal Watch 8(3): 193–204, September 2011.[1]
  5. ^ Cole, Daniel H.; Grossman, Peter Z. (2002-08-01). "The Meaning of Property Rights: Law versus Economics?". Land Economics. 78 (3): 317–330. doi:10.2307/3146892. ISSN 0023-7639.
  6. ^ a b c d e Cite error: The named reference NZ was invoked but never defined (see the help page).
  7. ^ a b Alchian, Armen A. (2018), "Property Rights", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 10892–10897, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1814, ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  8. ^ a b Sandmo, Agnar (1989), Eatwell, John; Milgate, Murray; Newman, Peter (eds.), "Public Goods", Allocation, Information and Markets, The New Palgrave, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 254–266, doi:10.1007/978-1-349-20215-7_26, ISBN 978-1-349-20215-7, retrieved 2021-04-26
  9. ^ Ostrom, Elinor; Hess, Charlotte (2007-11-29). "Private and Common Property Rights". Rochester, NY. doi:10.2139/ssrn.1936062. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  10. ^ Platteau, Jean-Philippe (2018), "Common Property Resources", The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, pp. 1868–1871, doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2085, ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  11. ^ Snidal, Duncan (1979-12-01). "Public Goods, Property Rights, and Political Organizations". International Studies Quarterly. 23 (4): 532–566. doi:10.2307/2600328. ISSN 0020-8833.
  12. ^ a b c T., Mahoney, Joseph (2005). Economic foundations of strategy. Sage. ISBN 1-4129-0542-7. OCLC 492090732.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link) CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  13. ^ Buchanan, James M (1965). "An Economic Theory of Clubs". Economica. 32 (125): 1–14.
  14. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1967). ""Toward a Theory of Property Rights."" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 57: 347–359.
  15. ^ See literature on post-regulatory approaches and reflexive law, especially literature from Gunther Teubner. See also the example of the 'conservation property right'
  16. ^ Coase, R. H. (1960-10-XX). "The Problem of Social Cost". The Journal of Law and Economics. 3: 1–44. doi:10.1086/466560. ISSN 0022-2186. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  17. ^ Property rights in a market system | Basic Economic Concepts | AP(R) Microeconomics | Khan Academy, retrieved 2021-04-26
  18. ^ Barzel, Yoram (April 1982). "Measurement Costs and the Organization of Markets". Journal of Law and Economics. 25 (1): 27–48. doi:10.1086/467005. ISSN 0022-2186. JSTOR 725223.
  19. ^ Douglas Allen (1991). What are Transaction Costs? (Research in Law and Economics). Jai Pr. ISBN 978-0-7623-1115-6.
  20. ^ "Property rights | Economics Online | Economics Online". 2020-01-17. Retrieved 2021-04-26.
  21. ^ Yoram., Barzel, (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-59275-5. OCLC 863296486.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link) CS1 maint: extra punctuation (link) CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  22. ^ Libecap, Gary D., ed. (1990), "Concluding remarks", Contracting for Property Rights, Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 115–121, doi:10.1017/cbo9780511664120.008, ISBN 978-0-521-44904-5, retrieved 2021-04-26
  23. ^ Besley, Timothy; Maitreesh, Ghatak (2009). Rodrik, Dani; Rosenzweig, Mark R (eds.). "Property Rights and Economic Development". Handbook of Development Economics. V: 4526–28.
  24. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James (2005). "Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth". Handbook of Economic Growth. 1: 397.
  25. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James A. (2005). Chapter 6 Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. Handbook of Economic Growth. Vol. 1. pp. 385–472. doi:10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01006-3. ISBN 978-0-444-52041-8.
  26. ^ Alchian, Armen A (1965). "Some Economics of Property Rights". II Politico. 30 (4): 816–829.
  27. ^ Demsetz, Harold (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights". American Economic Association. 57: 347–359.
  28. ^ Alchian, Armen; Demsetz, Harold (1973). "The Property Right Paradigm". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 16–27. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076403.
  29. ^ Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon; Robinson, James (2005). "Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth". Handbook of Economic Growth. Vol. 1. pp. 385–472.
  30. ^ North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2006). "A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history". National Bureau of Economic Research. 12795: 32–33.
  31. ^ North, Douglass C; Thomas, Robert P (1971). "The Rise and Fall of the Manorial System: A Theoretical Model". The Journal of Economic History. 31 (4): 777–803. doi:10.1017/S0022050700074623.
  32. ^ North, Douglass C; Wallis, John J; Weingast, Barry R (2009). "Violence and the Rise of Open-Access Orders". Journal of Democracy. 20 (1): 55–68. doi:10.1353/jod.0.0060.
  33. ^ Grossman, Sanford J.; Hart, Oliver D. (1986). "The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration". Journal of Political Economy. 94 (4): 691–719. doi:10.1086/261404. hdl:1721.1/63378. ISSN 0022-3808.
  34. ^ Hart, Oliver; Moore, John (1990). "Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm". Journal of Political Economy. 98 (6): 1119–1158. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.472.9089. doi:10.1086/261729. ISSN 0022-3808.
  35. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W. (2013). "Bargaining position, bargaining power, and the property rights approach" (PDF). Economics Letters. 119 (1): 28–31. doi:10.1016/j.econlet.2013.01.011.
  36. ^ Hart, Oliver; Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W. (1997). "The Proper Scope of Government: Theory and an Application to Prisons". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112 (4): 1127–1161. doi:10.1162/003355300555448. ISSN 0033-5533.
  37. ^ Hoppe, Eva I.; Schmitz, Patrick W. (2010). "Public versus private ownership: Quantity contracts and the allocation of investment tasks". Journal of Public Economics. 94 (3–4): 258–268. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.11.009.
  38. ^ Meza, David de; Lockwood, Ben (1998). "Does Asset Ownership Always Motivate Managers? Outside Options and the Property Rights Theory of the Firm". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 113 (2): 361–386. doi:10.1162/003355398555621. ISSN 0033-5533.
  39. ^ Chiu, Y. Stephen (1998). "Noncooperative Bargaining, Hostages, and Optimal Asset Ownership". The American Economic Review. 88 (4): 882–901. JSTOR 117010.
  40. ^ Schmitz, Patrick W (2006). "Information Gathering, Transaction Costs, and the Property Rights Approach". American Economic Review. 96 (1): 422–434. doi:10.1257/000282806776157722.
  41. ^ Mike Denison and Robyn Klingler-Vidra, October 2012, Annotated Bibliography for Rapid Review on Property Rights, Economics and Private Sector Professional Evidence and Applied Knowledge Services (EPS PEAKS)https://partnerplatform.org/?tcafmd80
  42. ^ Besley, Timothy, and Maitreesh Ghatak (2010). Handbook of Development Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier. pp. 4525–4595.
  43. ^ Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, A. Douglas (1972). "Property Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral". Harvard Law Review. 85 (6): 1089–1128. doi:10.2307/1340059. JSTOR 1340059.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  44. ^ Cavalli-Sforza, Luca L., Paolo Menozzi, and Alberto Piazza (1994). The History and Geography of Human Genes. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)