Jump to content

Pareto distribution: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
there was a mistake in the survival function: for x<x_m, P[X>x]=1, not 0 as was written before
Line 33: Line 33:
:<math>\overline{F}(x) = \Pr(X>x) = \begin{cases}
:<math>\overline{F}(x) = \Pr(X>x) = \begin{cases}
\left(\frac{x_\mathrm{m}}{x}\right)^\alpha & x\ge x_\mathrm{m}, \\
\left(\frac{x_\mathrm{m}}{x}\right)^\alpha & x\ge x_\mathrm{m}, \\
0 & x < x_\mathrm{m}.
1 & x < x_\mathrm{m}.
\end{cases}
\end{cases}
</math>
</math>

Revision as of 08:23, 11 January 2016

Pareto Type I
Probability density function
Pareto Type I probability density functions for various α
Pareto Type I probability density functions for various α with xm = 1. As α → ∞ the distribution approaches δ(x − xm) where δ is the Dirac delta function.
Cumulative distribution function
Pareto Type I cumulative distribution functions for various α
Pareto Type I cumulative distribution functions for various α with xm = 1.
Parameters xm > 0 scale (real)
α > 0 shape (real)
Support
PDF
CDF
Mean
Median
Mode
Variance
Skewness
Excess kurtosis
Entropy
MGF
CF
Fisher information

The Pareto distribution, named after the Italian civil engineer, economist, and sociologist Vilfredo Pareto, is a power law probability distribution that is used in description of social, scientific, geophysical, actuarial, and many other types of observable phenomena.

Definition

If X is a random variable with a Pareto (Type I) distribution,[1] then the probability that X is greater than some number x, i.e. the survival function (also called tail function), is given by

where xm is the (necessarily positive) minimum possible value of X, and α is a positive parameter. The Pareto Type I distribution is characterized by a scale parameter xm and a shape parameter α, which is known as the tail index. When this distribution is used to model the distribution of wealth, then the parameter α is called the Pareto index.

Properties

Cumulative distribution function

From the definition, the cumulative distribution function of a Pareto random variable with parameters α and xm is

When plotted on linear axes, the distribution assumes the familiar J-shaped curve which approaches each of the orthogonal axes asymptotically. All segments of the curve are self-similar (subject to appropriate scaling factors). When plotted in a log-log plot, the distribution is represented by a straight line.

Probability density function

It follows (by differentiation) that the probability density function is

Moments and characteristic function

(If α ≤ 1, the variance does not exist.)
where Γ(ax) is the incomplete gamma function.

Conditional distributions

The conditional probability distribution of a Pareto-distributed random variable, given the event that it is greater than or equal to a particular number  exceeding , is a Pareto distribution with the same Pareto index  but with minimum  instead of .

A characterization theorem

Suppose are independent identically distributed random variables whose probability distribution is supported on the interval for some . Suppose that for all , the two random variables and are independent. Then the common distribution is a Pareto distribution.[citation needed]

Geometric mean

The geometric mean (G) is[2]

Harmonic mean

The harmonic mean (H) is[2]

Generalized Pareto distributions

There is a hierarchy [1][3] of Pareto distributions known as Pareto Type I, II, III, IV, and Feller–Pareto distributions.[1][3][4] Pareto Type IV contains Pareto Type I–III as special cases. The Feller–Pareto[3][5] distribution generalizes Pareto Type IV.

Pareto types I–IV

The Pareto distribution hierarchy is summarized in the next table comparing the survival functions (complementary CDF).

When μ = 0, the Pareto distribution Type II is also known as the Lomax distribution.[6]

In this section, the symbol xm, used before to indicate the minimum value of x, is replaced by σ.

Pareto distributions
Support Parameters
Type I
Type II
Lomax
Type III
Type IV

The shape parameter α is the tail index, μ is location, σ is scale, γ is an inequality parameter. Some special cases of Pareto Type (IV) are

The finiteness of the mean, and the existence and the finiteness of the variance depend on the tail index α (inequality index γ). In particular, fractional δ-moments are finite for some δ > 0, as shown in the table below, where δ is not necessarily an integer.

Moments of Pareto I–IV distributions (case μ = 0)
Condition Condition
Type I
Type II
Type III
Type IV

Feller–Pareto distribution

Feller[3][5] defines a Pareto variable by transformation U = Y−1 − 1 of a beta random variable Y, whose probability density function is

where B( ) is the beta function. If

then W has a Feller–Pareto distribution FP(μ, σ, γ, γ1, γ2).[1]

If and are independent Gamma variables, another construction of a Feller–Pareto (FP) variable is[7]

and we write W ~ FP(μ, σ, γ, δ1, δ2). Special cases of the Feller–Pareto distribution are

Applications

Pareto originally used this distribution to describe the allocation of wealth among individuals since it seemed to show rather well the way that a larger portion of the wealth of any society is owned by a smaller percentage of the people in that society. He also used it to describe distribution of income.[8] This idea is sometimes expressed more simply as the Pareto principle or the "80-20 rule" which says that 20% of the population controls 80% of the wealth.[9] However, the 80-20 rule corresponds to a particular value of α, and in fact, Pareto's data on British income taxes in his Cours d'économie politique indicates that about 30% of the population had about 70% of the income. The probability density function (PDF) graph at the beginning of this article shows that the "probability" or fraction of the population that owns a small amount of wealth per person is rather high, and then decreases steadily as wealth increases. This distribution is not limited to describing wealth or income, but to many situations in which an equilibrium is found in the distribution of the "small" to the "large". The following examples are sometimes seen as approximately Pareto-distributed:

Fitted cumulative Pareto (Lomax) distribution to maximum one-day rainfalls using CumFreq, see also distribution fitting
  • Sizes of sand particles [10]
  • Sizes of meteorites
  • Numbers of species per genus (There is subjectivity involved: The tendency to divide a genus into two or more increases with the number of species in it)[citation needed]
  • Areas burnt in forest fires
  • Severity of large casualty losses for certain lines of business such as general liability, commercial auto, and workers compensation.[13][14]
  • In hydrology the Pareto distribution is applied to extreme events such as annually maximum one-day rainfalls and river discharges. The blue picture illustrates an example of fitting the Pareto distribution to ranked annually maximum one-day rainfalls showing also the 90% confidence belt based on the binomial distribution. The rainfall data are represented by plotting positions as part of the cumulative frequency analysis.

Relation to other distributions

Relation to the exponential distribution

The Pareto distribution is related to the exponential distribution as follows. If X is Pareto-distributed with minimum xm and index α, then

is exponentially distributed with rate parameter α. Equivalently, if Y is exponentially distributed with rate α, then

is Pareto-distributed with minimum xm and index α.

This can be shown using the standard change of variable techniques:

The last expression is the cumulative distribution function of an exponential distribution with rate α.

Relation to the log-normal distribution

Note that the Pareto distribution and log-normal distribution are alternative distributions for describing the same types of quantities. One of the connections between the two is that they are both the distributions of the exponential of random variables distributed according to other common distributions, respectively the exponential distribution and normal distribution.[citation needed]

Relation to the generalized Pareto distribution

The Pareto distribution is a special case of the generalized Pareto distribution, which is a family of distributions of similar form, but containing an extra parameter in such a way that the support of the distribution is either bounded below (at a variable point), or bounded both above and below (where both are variable), with the Lomax distribution as a special case. This family also contains both the unshifted and shifted exponential distributions.

The Pareto distribution with scale and shape is equivalent to the generalized Pareto distribution with location , scale and shape . Vice versa one can get the Pareto distribution from the GPD by and .

Relation to Zipf's law

Pareto distributions are continuous probability distributions. Zipf's law, also sometimes called the zeta distribution, may be thought of as a discrete counterpart of the Pareto distribution.

Relation to the "Pareto principle"

The "80-20 law", according to which 20% of all people receive 80% of all income, and 20% of the most affluent 20% receive 80% of that 80%, and so on, holds precisely when the Pareto index is α = log4(5) = log(5)/log(4), approximately 1.161. This result can be derived from the Lorenz curve formula given below. Moreover, the following have been shown[15] to be mathematically equivalent:

  • Income is distributed according to a Pareto distribution with index α > 1.
  • There is some number 0 ≤ p ≤ 1/2 such that 100p % of all people receive 100(1 − p) % of all income, and similarly for every real (not necessarily integer) n > 0, 100pn % of all people receive 100(1 − p)n percentage of all income.

This does not apply only to income, but also to wealth, or to anything else that can be modeled by this distribution.

This excludes Pareto distributions in which 0 < α ≤ 1, which, as noted above, have infinite expected value, and so cannot reasonably model income distribution.

Lorenz curve and Gini coefficient

Lorenz curves for a number of Pareto distributions. The case α = ∞ corresponds to perfectly equal distribution (G = 0) and the α = 1 line corresponds to complete inequality (G = 1)

The Lorenz curve is often used to characterize income and wealth distributions. For any distribution, the Lorenz curve L(F) is written in terms of the PDF f or the CDF F as

where x(F) is the inverse of the CDF. For the Pareto distribution,

and the Lorenz curve is calculated to be

Although the numerator and denominator in the expression for diverge for , their ratio does not, yielding L=0 in these cases, which yields a Gini coefficient of unity. Examples of the Lorenz curve for a number of Pareto distributions are shown in the graph on the right.

The Gini coefficient is a measure of the deviation of the Lorenz curve from the equidistribution line which is a line connecting [0, 0] and [1, 1], which is shown in black (α = ∞) in the Lorenz plot on the right. Specifically, the Gini coefficient is twice the area between the Lorenz curve and the equidistribution line. The Gini coefficient for the Pareto distribution is then calculated (for ) to be

(see Aaberge 2005).

Parameter estimation

The likelihood function for the Pareto distribution parameters α and xm, given a sample x = (x1x2, ..., xn), is

Therefore, the logarithmic likelihood function is

It can be seen that is monotonically increasing with xm, that is, the greater the value of xm, the greater the value of the likelihood function. Hence, since xxm, we conclude that

To find the estimator for α, we compute the corresponding partial derivative and determine where it is zero:

Thus the maximum likelihood estimator for α is:

The expected statistical error is:[16]

Malik (1970)[17] gives the exact joint distribution of . In particular, and are independent and is Pareto with scale parameter xm and shape parameter nα, whereas has an Inverse-gamma distribution with shape and scale parameters n−1 and nα, respectively.

Graphical representation

The characteristic curved 'Long Tail' distribution when plotted on a linear scale, masks the underlying simplicity of the function when plotted on a log-log graph, which then takes the form of a straight line with negative gradient: It follows from the formula for the probability density function that for xxm,

Since α is positive, the gradient −(α+1) is negative.

Random sample generation

Random samples can be generated using inverse transform sampling. Given a random variate U drawn from the uniform distribution on the unit interval (0, 1], the variate T given by

is Pareto-distributed.[18] If U is uniformly distributed on [0, 1), it can be exchanged with (1 − U).

Variants

Bounded Pareto distribution

Bounded Pareto
Parameters

location (real)
location (real)

shape (real)
Support
PDF
CDF
Mean
Median
Variance (this is the second moment, NOT the variance)[citation needed]
Skewness

(this is a formula for the kth moment, NOT the skewness)[citation needed]

The bounded (or truncated) Pareto distribution has three parameters α, L and H. As in the standard Pareto distribution α determines the shape. L denotes the minimal value, and H denotes the maximal value. (The variance in the table on the right should be interpreted as the second moment).

The probability density function is

where L ≤ x ≤ H, and α > 0.

Generating bounded Pareto random variables

If U is uniformly distributed on (0, 1), then applying inverse-transform method [19]

is a bounded Pareto-distributed. [citation needed]

Symmetric Pareto distribution

The symmetric Pareto distribution can be defined by the probability density function:[20]

It has a similar shape to a Pareto distribution for x > xm and is mirror symmetric about the vertical axis.

See also

Notes

  1. ^ a b c d Barry C. Arnold (1983). Pareto Distributions. International Co-operative Publishing House. ISBN 0-89974-012-X. {{cite book}}: Invalid |ref=harv (help)
  2. ^ a b Johnson NL, Kotz S, Balakrishnan N (1994) Continuous univariate distributions Vol 1. Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics.
  3. ^ a b c d Johnson, Kotz, and Balakrishnan (1994), (20.4).
  4. ^ Christian Kleiber and Samuel Kotz (2003). Statistical Size Distributions in Economics and Actuarial Sciences. Wiley. ISBN 0-471-15064-9. {{cite book}}: Invalid |ref=harv (help)
  5. ^ a b Feller, W. (1971). An Introduction to Probability Theory and its Applications. Vol. II (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley. p. 50. "The densities (4.3) are sometimes called after the economist Pareto. It was thought (rather naïvely from a modern statistical standpoint) that income distributions should have a tail with a density ~ Ax−α as x → ∞."
  6. ^ Lomax, K. S. (1954). Business failures. Another example of the analysis of failure data.Journal of the American Statistical Association, 49, 847–852.
  7. ^ Chotikapanich, Duangkamon. "Chapter 7: Pareto and Generalized Pareto Distributions". Modeling Income Distributions and Lorenz Curves. pp. 121–122.
  8. ^ Pareto, Vilfredo, Cours d'Économie Politique: Nouvelle édition par G.-H. Bousquet et G. Busino, Librairie Droz, Geneva, 1964, pages 299–345.
  9. ^ For a two-quantile population, where approximately 18% of the population owns 82% of the wealth, the Theil index takes the value 1.
  10. ^ a b c d e Reed, William J.; et al. (2004.). "The Double Pareto-Lognormal Distribution – A New Parametric Model for Size Distributions". Communications in Statistics – Theory and Methods. 33 (8): 1733–1753. doi:10.1081/sta-120037438. CiteSeerx10.1.1.70.4555. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |year= (help)CS1 maint: year (link)
  11. ^ Schroeder, Bianca; Damouras, Sotirios; Gill, Phillipa (2010-02-24). "Understanding latent sector error and how to protect against them" (PDF). 8th Usenix Conference on File and Storage Technologies (FAST 2010). Retrieved 2010-09-10. We experimented with 5 different distributions (Geometric,Weibull, Rayleigh, Pareto, and Lognormal), that are commonly used in the context of system reliability, and evaluated their fit through the total squared differences between the actual and hypothesized frequencies (χ2 statistic). We found consistently across all models that the geometric distribution is a poor fit, while the Pareto distribution provides the best fit.
  12. ^ Yuji Ijiri; Simon, Herbert A. (May 1975). "Some Distributions Associated with Bose–Einstein Statistics". Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA. 72 (5): 1654–1657. PMC 432601. PMID 16578724. {{cite journal}}: |access-date= requires |url= (help)
  13. ^ Kleiber and Kotz (2003): page 94.
  14. ^ Seal, H. (1980). "Survival probabilities based on Pareto claim distributions". ASTIN Bulletin. 11: 61–71.
  15. ^ Hardy, Michael (2010). "Pareto's Law". Mathematical Intelligencer. 32 (3): 38–43. doi:10.1007/s00283-010-9159-2.
  16. ^ M. E. J. Newman (2005). "Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf's law". Contemporary Physics. 46 (5): 323–351. arXiv:cond-mat/0412004. Bibcode:2005ConPh..46..323N. doi:10.1080/00107510500052444.
  17. ^ H. J. Malik (1970). "Estimation of the Parameters of the Pareto Distribution". Metrika. 15.
  18. ^ Tanizaki, Hisashi (2004). Computational Methods in Statistics and Econometrics. CRC Press. p. 133.
  19. ^ http://www.cs.bgu.ac.il/~mps042/invtransnote.htm
  20. ^ Grabchak, M. & Samorodnitsky, D. "Do Financial Returns Have Finite or Infinite Variance? A Paradox and an Explanation" (PDF). pp. 7–8.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)

References

  • M. O. Lorenz (1905). "Methods of measuring the concentration of wealth". Publications of the American Statistical Association. 9 (70): 209–219. Bibcode:1905PAmSA...9..209L. doi:10.2307/2276207.
  • Pareto V (1965) "La Courbe de la Repartition de la Richesse" (Originally published in 1896). In: Busino G, editor. Oevres Completes de Vilfredo Pareto. Geneva: Librairie Droz. pp. 1–5.
  • Pareto, V. (1895). La legge della domanda. Giornale degli Economisti, 10, 59–68. English translation in Rivista di Politica Economica, 87 (1997), 691–700.
  • Pareto, V. (1897). Cours d'économie politique. Lausanne: Ed. Rouge.

Template:Common univariate probability distributions