David Ricardo: Difference between revisions
m →Ideas: fixed disambig link |
|||
Line 14: | Line 14: | ||
==Personal life== |
==Personal life== |
||
Born in [[London]], Ricardo was the third of seventeen children |
Born in [[London]], Ricardo was the third of seventeen children of a man from a [[Sephardi|Sephardic Jewish]] family (originally from [[Portugal]]) who eloped with a [[Religious Society of Friends|Quaker]], Priscilla Anne Wilkinson, when he was 21, leading to estrangement from his family. It seems that his mother never spoke to him again. He had eight children including three sons, of whom Osman Ricardo (1795-1881; MP for [[Worcester (UK Parliament constituency)|Worcester]] 1847-1865) and another David Ricardo (1803-1864, MP for [[Stroud (UK Parliament constituency)|Stroud]] 1832-1833) became members of parliament, while the third, Mortimer Ricardo, served as an officer in the [[Life Guards]] and was a [[deputy lieutenant]] for [[Oxfordshire]]. He married at about the same time as he became a teacher at Gravesend Grammar School [[Unitarianism|Unitarian]].{{Fact|date=February 2008}} He was one of the original members of [[The Geological Society]]. |
||
Ricardo became interested in economics after reading [[Adam Smith]]'s ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' in 1799 on a vacation to the English resort of [[Bath, Somerset|Bath]]. This was Ricardo's first contact with economics. He wrote his first economics article at age 37 and within another ten years he reached the height of his fame. |
Ricardo became interested in economics after reading [[Adam Smith]]'s ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' in 1799 on a vacation to the English resort of [[Bath, Somerset|Bath]]. This was Ricardo's first contact with economics. He wrote his first economics article at age 37 and within another ten years he reached the height of his fame. |
Revision as of 00:46, 25 September 2008
David Ricardo, MP | |
---|---|
Born | |
Died | 11 September 1823 | (aged 51)
David Ricardo (18 April 1772 – 11 September 1823) was an English political economist, often credited with systematizing economics, and was one of the most influential of the classical economists, along with Thomas Malthus and Adam Smith. He was also a member of Parliament, businessman, financier and speculator, and amassed a considerable fortune.
Personal life
Born in London, Ricardo was the third of seventeen children of a man from a Sephardic Jewish family (originally from Portugal) who eloped with a Quaker, Priscilla Anne Wilkinson, when he was 21, leading to estrangement from his family. It seems that his mother never spoke to him again. He had eight children including three sons, of whom Osman Ricardo (1795-1881; MP for Worcester 1847-1865) and another David Ricardo (1803-1864, MP for Stroud 1832-1833) became members of parliament, while the third, Mortimer Ricardo, served as an officer in the Life Guards and was a deputy lieutenant for Oxfordshire. He married at about the same time as he became a teacher at Gravesend Grammar School Unitarian.[citation needed] He was one of the original members of The Geological Society.
Ricardo became interested in economics after reading Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations in 1799 on a vacation to the English resort of Bath. This was Ricardo's first contact with economics. He wrote his first economics article at age 37 and within another ten years he reached the height of his fame.
Ricardo's work with the stock exchange made him quite wealthy, which allowed him to retire from business in 1814 at the age of 42. He then purchased and moved to Gatcombe Park, an estate in Gloucestershire.
In 1819, Ricardo took a seat in the House of Commons as the MP for Portarlington, an Irish rotten borough. He held the seat, which had initially been made available to him by his friend,Conversation Sharp, until his death in 1823. In 1846 his nephew, John Lewis Ricardo, MP for Stoke-on-Trent, advocated free trade and the repeal of the Corn Laws.
Ricardo was a close friend of James Mill, who encouraged him in his political ambitions and writings about economics. Other notable friends included Jeremy Bentham and Thomas Malthus, with whom Ricardo had a considerable debate (in correspondence) over such things as the role of land owners in a society. He also was a member of London's intellectuals, later becoming a member of Malthus' Political Economy Club, and a member of the King of Clubs.
Ideas
Ricardo's most famous work is his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817). Ricardo opens the first chapter with a statement of the labour theory of value. Later in this chapter, he demonstrates that prices do not correspond to this value. He retained the theory, however, as an approximation. The labour theory of value states that the relative price of two goods is determined by the ratio of the quantities of labour required in their production. His labour theory of value, however, required several assumptions: 1) both sectors have the same wage rate and the same profit rate; 2) the capital employed in production is made up of wages only; 3) the period of production has the same length for both goods. Ricardo himself realized that the second and third assumptions were quite unrealistic and hence admitted two exceptions to his labour theory of value: 1) production periods may differ; 2) the two production processes may employ instruments and equipment as capital and not just wages, and in very different proportions. Ricardo continued to work on his value theory to the end of his life.
This book introduces the theory of comparative advantage. According to Ricardo's theory, even if a country could produce everything more efficiently than another country, it would reap gains from specializing in what it was best at producing and trading with other nations. (Case & Fair, 1999: 812–818). Ricardo believed that wages should be left to free competition, so there should be no restrictions on the importation of agricultural products from abroad.
The benefits of comparative advantage are both distributional and related to improved real income. Within Ricardo's theory, distributional effects implied that foreign trade could not directly affect profits, because profits change only in response to the level of wages. The effects on income are always beneficial because foreign trade does not affect value.
Comparative advantage forms the basis of modern trade theory, reformulated as the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem, which states that a country has a comparative advantage in the production of a product if the country is relatively well-endowed with inputs that are used intensively in producing the product. (Case & Fair 1999, p. 822).
Like Adam Smith, Ricardo was also an opponent of protectionism for national economies, especially for agriculture. He believed that the British "Corn Laws" — tariffs on agriculture products — ensured that less productive domestic land would be harvested and rents would be driven up. (Case & Fair 1999, pp. 812, 813). Thus, the surplus would be directed more toward feudal landlords and away from the emerging industrial capitalists. Since landlords tended to squander their wealth on luxuries, rather than investments, Ricardo believed that the Corn Laws were leading to the economic stagnation of the British economy. Parliament repealed the Corn Laws in 1846.
Another idea associated with Ricardo is Ricardian equivalence, an argument suggesting that in some circumstances a government's choice of how to pay for its spending (i.e., whether to use tax revenue or issue debt and run a deficit) might have no effect on the economy. Ironically, while the proposition bears his name, he does not seem to have believed it. Economist Robert Barro is responsible for its modern prominence.
Ricardo is responsible for developing theories of rent, wages, and profits. He defined rent as "the difference between the produce obtained by the employment of two equal quantities of capital and labor." The model for this theory basically said that while only one grade of land is being used for cultivation, rent will not exist, but when multiple grades of land are being utilised, rent will be charged on the higher grades and will increase with the ascension of the grade. As such, Ricardo believed that the process of economic development, which increased land utilisation and eventually led to the cultivation of poorer land, benefited first and foremost the landowners because they would receive the rent payments either in money or in product.
Ricardo's theories of wages and profits
Ricardo believed that in the long run, prices reflect the cost of production, and referred to this long run price as a Natural price. The natural price of labour was the cost of its production, that cost of maintaining the labourer. If wages correspond to the natural price of labour, then wages would be at subsistence level. However, due to an improving economy, wages may remain indefinitely above subsistence level:
Notwithstanding the tendency of wages to conform to their natural rate, their market rate may, in an improving society, for an indefinite period, be constantly above it; for no sooner may the impulse, which an increased capital gives to a new demand for labour, be obeyed, than another increase of capital may produce the same effect; and thus, if the increase of capital be gradual and constant, the demand for labour may give a continued stimulus to an increase of people.…
It has been calculated, that under favourable circumstances population may be doubled in twenty-five years; but under the same favourable circumstances, the whole capital of a country might possibly be doubled in a shorter period. In that case, wages during the whole period would have a tendency to rise, because the demand for labour would increase still faster than the supply. (On the Principles of Political Economy, Chapter 5, "On Wages").
In his Theory of Profit, Ricardo stated that as real wages increase, real profits decrease because the revenue from the sale of manufactured goods is split between profits and wages. He said in his Essay on Profits, "Profits depend on high or low wages, wages on the price of necessaries, and the price of necessaries chiefly on the price of food."
Publications
Ricardo's publications included:
- The High Price of Bullion, a Proof of the Depreciation of Bank Notes (1810), which advocated the adoption of a metallic currency
- Essay on the Influence of a Low Price of Corn on the Profits of Stock (1815), which argued that repealing the Corn Laws would distribute more wealth to the productive members of society
- On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), an analysis that concluded that land rent grows as population increases. It also clearly laid out the theory of comparative advantage, which showed that all nations could benefit from free trade, even if a nation was less efficient at producing all kinds of goods than its trading partners.
References
- Case, Karl E.; Fair, Ray C. (1999), Principles of Economics (5th ed.), Prentice-Hall, ISBN 0-13-961905-4
- Samuel Hollander (1979)). The Economics of David Ricardo. University of Toronto Press.
- G. de Vivo (1987). "Ricardo, David," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, pp. 183-98.
- P. A. Samuelson (2001). "Ricardo, David (1772–1823)," International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, pp. 13330-13334. Abstract.
External links
- On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, by David Ricardo. Complete, fully-searchable text at the Library of Economics and Liberty.
- Biography, at the Concise Encyclopedia of Economics
- Biography at New School University
- Biography at EH.Net Encyclopedia of Economic History
- The Works of David Ricardo (McCulloch edition 1888) at the Online Library of Liberty
- The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo (Sraffa edition) 11 vols at the Online Library of Liberty
- Timeline of the Life of David Ricardo (1772-1823) at the Online Library of Liberty
- 1772 births
- 1823 deaths
- English economists
- Classical economists
- Classical liberals
- Utilitarians
- Members of the United Kingdom Parliament for Irish constituencies (1801-1922)
- Members of the United Kingdom Parliament for English constituencies
- International trade
- International economics
- UK MPs 1818-1820
- UK MPs 1820-1826
- English Unitarians
- British Jews
- English Quakers
- Spanish and Portuguese Jews
- Converts from Judaism to Christianity
- Jewish scientists
- Trade economists