Jump to content

Free banking

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Melt core (talk | contribs) at 11:39, 4 July 2014. The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

Free banking refers to a monetary arrangement in which banks are subject to no special regulations beyond those applicable to most enterprises, and in which they also are free to issue their own paper currency (banknotes). In a free banking system, market forces control the supply of total quantity of banknotes and deposits that can be supported by any given stock of cash reserves, where such reserves consist either of a scarce commodity (such as gold) or of an artificially limited stock of "fiat" money issued by a central bank. In the strictest versions of free banking, however, there either is no role at all for a central bank, or the supply of central bank money is supposed to be permanently "frozen." There is, therefore, no agency capable of serving as a "lender of last resort" in the usually understood sense of the term. Nor is there any government insurance of banknotes or bank deposit accounts.[1]

Supporters include Fred Foldvary,[2] David D. Friedman,[3] Friedrich Hayek,[4] George Selgin,[5] Lawrence H. White.[6] Steven Horwitz,[7] and Richard Timberlake.[8]

History

The free banking movement got its modern start in 1977 with The Denationalization of Money, by economist Friedrich Hayek, who advocated that national governments stop claiming a monopoly on the issuing of currency, and allow private issuers like banks to voluntarily compete to do so.

In the 1980s, this expanded into an increasingly elaborate theory of free market money and banking, with proponents Lawrence White, George Selgin, and Charles Timberlake increasingly centering their writing and research around the concept, either regarding modern theory and application, or researching the history of spontaneously free banking.

Banking has been more regulated in some times and places than others, and some times and places it has hardly been regulated at all, giving some experiences of more or less free banking.

  1. Australia. In the late 19th century, banking in Australia was subject to little regulation. There were four large banks with over 100 branches each, that together had about half of the banking business, and branch banking and deposit banking were much more advanced than other more regulated countries such as the UK and USA. Banks accepted each other's notes at par. Interest margins were about 4% p.a. In the 1890s a land price crash caused the failure of many smaller banks and building societies. Bankruptcy legislation put in place at the time gave bank debtors generous terms they could restructure under, and most of the banks used this as a means to restructure their debts in their favor, even though they didn't really need to.
  2. Switzerland.[9] In the 19th Century several Swiss cantons deregulated banking, allowing free entry and issue of notes. Cantons retained jurisdiction over banking until the enactment of the Federal Banking Law of 1881. The centralisation of note issue reduced the problem of the existence of "a bewildering variety of notes of varying qualities ... at fluctuating exchange rates."[10]
  3. Scottish Free Banking.[9] This period lasted between 1716 and 1845. The Bank of Scotland, the original Scottish bank charter and The Royal Bank of Scotland, chartered by England, issued competitive currencies. This resulted in a "currency war" in 1727. The result was a cooperative equilibrium, where both banks agreed to accept rival banks' notes in the ordinary course of business. This area of study has been developed further by Lawrence H. White in his book Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debate 1800-1845.[11]
  4. United States.[9] Although the period from 1837 to 1864 in the U.S. is often referred to as the Free Banking Era, the term is something of a misnomer, for it refers not to a general system of "free" banking in the literal sense described previously, but rather to various state banking systems based on so-called "free banking" laws, which, though they made it unnecessary for new entrants to secure charters (each of which was subject to a vote by the state legislature), nonetheless restricted their undertakings in important ways.[12][13][14][15] Most importantly, U.S. "free" banks were denied the right to establish branch networks, and had to "secure" their notes by purchasing and surrendering to state banking authorities certain securities those authorities deemed eligible for the purpose. The securities in many cases included bonds of the authorizing state governments themselves; and it has been determined that the depreciation of these very securities was the chief cause of "free bank" failures, and indeed of bank failures generally, during the period in question. The lack of branch banking, in turn, caused state-issued banknotes to be discounted at varying rates once they had traveled any considerable distance from their sources. In short, the shortcomings of banks and bank-supplied paper currency during the so-called "free banking era" in the U.S., far from establishing the need for special regulation of banks, testifies to the dangers of unwarranted or unwise regulation.[16] Then, from 1863 to 1913, known as the National Banks Era, state-chartered banks were operating under a free banking system. Some scholars have found that the system was mostly stable compared to National Banks of that era.[17]
  5. Sweden.[9] Sweden had two periods of free banking, 1830–60 and 1860-1902. Following a bank crisis in 1857, there was a rise in popular support for private banks and private money issuers (especially Stockholms Enskilda Bank, founded in 1856). A new bank law was adopted by parliament in 1864, deregulating the interest rate. The following decades marked the height of the Swedish free banking era. After 1874, no new private banks were founded. In 1901, issuing of private money was prohibited. Research on the Swedish free banking era suggest stability, and a single bank failure related to fraud in 70 years.[18][19]

In the early twenty-first century, the advent of electronic currencies such as the Bitcoin have renewed the question of private money.[20][21][22]

See also

  • Henry Meulen, author of Free Banking: An Outline of a Policy on Individualism, 1934
  • Richard Salsman, author of Breaking the Banks: Central Banking Problems and Free Banking Solutions, 1990

References

  1. ^ Selgin, George A.; White, Lawrence H. (1994). "How Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?". Journal of Economic Literature. 32 (4): 1718–1749.
  2. ^ Foldvary, Fred E. (November 2008). "Free Banking Explained". The Progress Report.
  3. ^ Friedman, David D. (1982-09-23). "Gold, Paper, Or...Is There a Better Money?". Policy Analysis No. 17. Cato Institute. Retrieved 2012-03-08.
  4. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1976). The Denationalisation of Money. Coronet Books. ISBN 978-0-255-36239-9.
  5. ^ "Interview: George Selgin". Region Focus. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Winter 2009. Retrieved 2012-03-08.
  6. ^ "Dr. Lawrence H. White". Foundation for Economic Education. 2008-12-23. Retrieved 2012-03-08.
  7. ^ Horwitz, Steven (1992). Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order. Westview Press. ISBN 0-8133-8514-8.
  8. ^ Timberlake, Richard; Dowd, Kevin (1998). Money and the Nation State. Transaction Publishers.
  9. ^ a b c d Briones, Ignacio; Rockoff, Hugh (August 2005). "Do Economists Reach a Conclusion on Free-Banking Episodes?". Econ Journal Watch. 2 (2): 279–324.
  10. ^ Goodhart, Charles Albert Eric (1995). The Central Bank and the Financial System. MIT Press. p. 211.
  11. ^ White, Lawrence H. (1995). Free Banking in Britain: Theory, Experience and Debate 1800-1845. London: Institute of Economic Affairs. ISBN 0-255-36375-3.
  12. ^ Ng, Kenneth (1988). "Free Banking Laws and Barriers to Entry in Banking, 1838-1860". The Journal of Economic History. 48 (4): 877–889. doi:10.1017/s0022050700006653.
  13. ^ Bodenhorn, Howard (1990). "Entry, Rivalry and Free Banking in Antebellum America". Review of Economics & Statistics. 72 (4): 682–686. doi:10.2307/2109610.
  14. ^ Economopoulous, Andrew; O'Neill, Heather (1995). "Bank Entry during the Antebellum Period". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 27 (4): 1071–1085. doi:10.2307/2077790.
  15. ^ Rockoff, Hugh (1989). "Lessons from the American Experience with Free Banking". NBER Historical Working Paper No. 9.
  16. ^ Calomiris, Charles W. (2010). "The Great Depression and Other 'Contagious' Events". In Berger, Allen N; Molyneux, Philip; Wilson, John O. S. (eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Banking. Oxford University Press. pp. 693–710.
  17. ^ Freixas, Xavier; Rochet, Jean-Charles (1997). Microeconomics of Banking. MIT Press. p. 261.
  18. ^ Hortlund, Per (2007). "The Provision of Liquidity in the Swedish Note Banking System, 1878–1901". Scandinavian Economic History Review. 5 (1): 20–40.
  19. ^ Lakomaa, Erik (2007). "Free Banking in Sweden 1830–1903: Experience and Debate" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 10 (2): 25–44.
  20. ^ US House of Representatives. Committee on Financial Services. Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology (May 8, 2012). "Improving the Federal Reserve System: Examining Legislation to Reform the Fed and Other Alternatives. Written Testimony by Jeffrey M. Herbener, Professor of Economics, Grove City College" (PDF). {{cite web}}: |author= has generic name (help)
  21. ^ Hulsmann, Guido Jorg (2008). Ethics of Money Production. Ludwig von Mises Institute.
  22. ^ Feuer, Alan (October 24, 2012). "Prison May Be the Next Stop on a Gold Currency Journey". The New York Times.
  • Alan Ebenstein. Friedrich Hayek: A Biography. University of Chicago Press, 2003. Print.
  • George Selgin. The Theory of Free Banking. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc., 1988. Print.
  • Lawrence H. White. Competition and Currency: Essays on Free Banking and Money. New York University Press, 1992. Print.