Jump to content

User:G.cusumano/Piero Sraffa

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Piero Sraffa (5 August 1898 – 3 September 1983) was an influential Italian economist who served as lecturer of economics at the University of Cambridge. His book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities is taken as founding the neo-Ricardian school of economics.


Early life

[edit]

Sraffa was born in Turin, Italy, to Angelo Sraffa (1865–1937) and Irma Sraffa (née Tivoli) (1873–1949) a wealthy Italian Jewish couple. His father was a professor in commercial law and later dean at the Bocconi University in Milan. Despite being raised as a practising Jew, Sraffa later became an agnostic.[citation needed] He studied in his home town and graduated at the local university with a work on inflation in Italy during and after World War I. [IMPRECISE – EXPLAINED IN THE THREE FOLLOWING LINES] Due to his father's activity, the young Piero followed him during his academic wanderings (University of Parma, University of Milan e University of Turin). He attended the faculty of Jurisprudence at the University of Turin, where he met Antonio Gramsci (later the most important leader of the Italian Communist Party) [THIS PARTY WAS FOUNDED TWO YERAS LATER].They became close friends, partly due to their shared political views [IMPRECISE]. Sraffa was also in contact with Filippo Turati, perhaps the most important leader of the Italian Socialist Party, whom he allegedly met and frequently visited in Rapallo, where his family had a holiday villa.

At the age of 18, in the spring of 1917  he began military service as an officer of the Military Engineer Corps, under the command of the First Army as rear-guard. From the end of World War I (November 1918 ) until March of 1920 he was a member of the Royal commission of inquiry into the violations of the right of the people committed by the enemy. The military period corresponded to the "university" one; some anecdotes tell of exams done effortlessly wearing the officer uniform. He graduated in November 1920 with a thesis on inflation in Italy during the period of the Great War. His tutor was Luigi Einaudi, one of the most important Italian economists and later a president of the Italian Republic.

From 1921 to 1922, he studied at the London School of Economics. In this period, at Cambridge, he met John Maynard Keynes twice  who invited him to a collaboration. This request led Sraffa to write two articles about the Italian banking system which were published in the 1922. The first ( The Bank Crisis in Italy ) was published in The Economic Journal  (directed by Keynes) and the second (The current situation of Italian banks) in the supplement of the newspaper Manchester Guardian (now The Guardian ). Keynes also  entrusted Sraffa with the Italian edition of his A Tract on Monetary Reform. The meeting with Keynes was undoubtedly a fundamental turning point of Sraffa's biography.

In 1922, he was appointed director of the provincial labour department in Milan, where he frequented socialist circles. In this period he made friends with Carlo Rosselli and Raffaele Mattioli, both assistants of Luigi Einaudi at the time.

The march on Rome, with the consequent seizure of power by Mussolini, was an event destined to affect deeply his future. His father Angelo was the object of a fascist squad aggression and received

two very threatening telegrams by Mussolini himself who required a public retraction by Piero on the content of the second article published in the Manchester Guardian.[1] Piero did not write a retraction.

In November of 1923, he was appointed as a lecturer in political economy first in Perugia. In his course of Political economy he adopted Marshall’s  Principles.  and later in Cagliari (Sardinia). In March of 1926, he became full professor of Economics in Cagliari.

In May of 1924 his friend Antonio Gramsci, who found himself stuck firstly in Moscow and then in Vienna due to the advent to power of fascism, returned to Rome on his election to parliament. From now on until his arrest) the relations between the two intellectuals intensified. In the 26th of November of 1926 Italian Parliament approved the  law "defence of the state", thus giving rise to the totalitarian state. On 8th of November of 1926 Antonio Gramsci was arrested.   During Gramsci’s incarceration Sraffa supplied books and the material, literally pens and paper, with which Gramsci would write his Prison Notebooks.

Major works

The laws of productivity under competitive conditions

In 1925, Sraffa  wrote about returns to scale and perfect competition.[2] underlining some doubtful points of Alfred Marshall's theory of the firm. This was amended nd published in 1926 as  In the 1926 article, The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions, published in The Economic Journal, Sraffa resumes and develops his work of 1925  to show the inconsistency of the Marshallian theory  of partial equilibrium prices, according to which, in competition for each good:

1) the equilibrium price is determined by the intersection of the demand curve and

that of the supply. The supply curve is symmetrical to that of the demand.

2)  As the quantity produced by the firm increases, there are initially increasing returns and, beyond a certain point, decreasing returns.


Sraffa notes that the law of decreasing returns and that of increasing returns have different origins and areas of application (and therefore cannot explain the shape of the same supply curve): the law of diminishing returns was originally applied to the entire economy and resulted from the scarcity of the agricultural land as a means of production (the rent theory of David Ricardo) ; while the law of increasing returns applied to the individual firm and resulted from the benefits of division of labour. The first one allowed for the study of the laws of distribution, the second those of production.[3]

“[N]obody, until comparatively recently - Sraffa writes - had thought of unifying these two tendencies in one single law of non-proportional productivity, and considering this as one  of the bases of the theory of price.”[4]  Sraffa observes that the idea of considering the law of non-proportional returns as a basis for the price theory arose, for analogy, only after the study of decreasing utility had drawn attention to the relationship between the price and the quantity consumed. In fact, “if the cost of production of every unit of the commodity under consideration did not vary with variations in quantity produced the symmetry would be broken, the price  would be determined exclusively by the expanses of production and demand would be unable to have any influence on it at all”.[5]

The difficulties of the system that could, in short, be defined as the cross of the supply and demand curves firstly depend on the heterogeneity of the assumptions on which these two different tendencies are based. Decreasing returns and increasing costs are caused by the limited availability of some input which prevents all inputs from varying in optimal proportion.  In other words, if an input is limited in quantity, a rise in production levels brings about a less efficient proportion among inputs with a fall in productivity. By contrast, the tendency toward decreasing costs stems from variations in the quantity of all inputs,  and therefore they may occur only when there are no constant factors.[6]

A second difficulty stems from the fact that, as Sraffa notes,  in the neoclassical theory of prices the equilibrium of the individual firm  is determined on the basis of cost variations deriving from small increases in its production (marginalist theory) and taking the situation unchanged in other companies of the same industry and the entire economy, following the hypothesis of ceteris paribus, i.e. other conditions being equal.[7]

Sraffa highlights that the possibility of applying the hypothesis of increasing costs to the supply curve is limited to the rare cases in which a considerable part of the supply of  an input is employed for the production of only one commodity.  However, in general each input is employed by a certain number of industries that produce different goods.[8]

As for increasing returns and decreasing costs, Marshall himself notes that external economies can hardly be attributed clearly to a specific industry, but they are of considerable interest to groups, often of a large size, in related industries; consequently, it is not possible to hypothesize an increase in returns in just one company.[9]

If in the partial equilibrium system of competitive prices it is not possible to consider decreasing or increasing costs without contradicting the nature of the system, it follow, from this point of view, that production costs of goods produced in competition must be regarded as constant  in respect of small variations in the quantity produced”[10] and that the long-run supply curve of a industry is horizontal. As a consequence, the price and the quantity of a good do not derive from the simultaneous action of the supply and demand curves: the price is determined by production costs, while the quantity produced is determined by the demand. The neoclassic symmetry between demand and supply is broken. The old  theory  that, in competition, “makes the value of commodities dependent on the cost of production alone appears to hold its  ground as the best available" (1926b:540-1).[11]

Finally, Sraffa remarks that “everyday experience shows that the majority of  which produce manufactured consumers’ goods operate in conditions of individual diminishing costs. If the

Limit to the firm’s expansion does not arise from increasing costs, then it may arise from the difficulty in expanding the market share without changing any of these three aspects: improving the quality of the output, reducing its price, or increasing marketing expanses. These considerations were developed, in the 1930s, by  theory of imperfect competition.

The Cambridge years

In 1927, Sraffa's yet undiscussed theory of value, but also his friendship with Antonio Gramsci —a risky and compromising endeavour in the context of the Italian fascist regime, considering Gramsci had previously been imprisoned — brought John Maynard Keynes to prudently invite Sraffa to the University of Cambridge, where the Italian economist was initially assigned a lectureship.

Sraffa arrived in July of 1927 and remained there for life. In the shelter of the English city, he held courses about advanced value theory in his first three years. Then, again with the help of Keynes, he held a librarian position and could devote himself to study, intertwining relationships with a series of intellectuals destined to leave remarkable and lasting tracks.

Together with Frank P. Ramsey and Ludwig Wittgenstein, Sraffa joined the so-called cafeteria group, an informal club that discussed Keynes's theory of probability and Friedrich Hayek's theory of business cycles (see Sraffa–Hayek debate). The economists that should at least be remembered are Michał Kalecki ( 1899 - 1970 ), Maurice Dobb ( 1900 - 1976 ), Joan Robinson ( 1903 - 1983 ) e Nicholas Kaldor ( 1908 - 1986 ). Among the philosophers, Frank Plumpton Ramsey ( 1903 - 1930 ) was helpful during the initial elaboration of the equations, datable in 1928, of the book Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, which was published in 1960.

In the early thirties there was a controversy between Sraffa and Friedrich von Hayek, who published a criticism of Keynes's conclusions contained in Treatise on Money (1930).[12] After a first reply, Keynes asked Sraffa about writing a more detailed answer to Hayek's theses. Sraffa thoroughly analyzed the inconsistencies logic of Hayek's theory on the effect of forced capital savings caused by inflation and above all on the definition of natural interest rate.[13] The debate continued with a reply by Hayek and a rejoinder by Sraffa.

In 1939, Sraffa was elected to a fellowship at Trinity College.

Luigi Pasinetti  identifies five stages of his work in Cambridge.

1)                1928-1931: research on the history of economic theories, aimed at recovering the

"reasonable" economics of the classics. Sraffa intends to “go straight to the unknown, from Marshall to Marx, from disutility to material cost ".

2)                1931-1940: edition of Ricardo's works; almost ready for printing, they don't get

published both because the "Introduction" (written by Sraffa later) is missing, and because of the

discovery of new documents, including all Ricardo's letters to James Mill.

3)                1941-1945: criticism of the neoclassical economics, in particular of the theory of production

and distribution of the theory of value (of prices), of the theory of marginal utility and

of the theory of interest as a reward for abstinence; processing of his equations

with surplus.

4)                1946-1955: publication of the first ten volumes of Ricardo's works (the eleventh,

containing the General Index, is published in 1973). John Eatwell wrote of Sraffa's work on David Ricardo:

[Sraffa's] reconstruction of Ricardo's surplus theory, presented in but a few pages of the introduction to his edition of Ricardo's Principles, penetrated a hundred years of misunderstanding and distortion to create a vivid rationale for the structure and content of surplus theory, for the analytical role of the labour theory of value, and hence for the foundations of Marx's critical analysis of capitalist production.

5)                1955-1960: preparation of Production of Goods by Means of Goods as mere "premise

to a critique of political economy "; the original project proved too vast:

of the historical part remains only an appendix of a few pages entitled "Note on the sources"

and it is hoped in the Preface that the real criticism will be attempted "later, or

by the author or someone younger and better equipped for the company ".

Ricardo's works and correspondence [I MOVED IT ABOVE]

Sraffian economics Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities

The critique of neo-classical price theory based on the relations between cost and quantity produced leads Sraffa to abandon the analysis of partial equilibrium.  Since the late 1920's, he begins to work on a price theory that takes up the classical concepts of reproducibility, surplus, circularity of production, and freedom of entry.[14]  In his book, Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, published only in 1960, Sraffa focuses on the analysis of relative prices and income distribution, assuming "no changes in output and ... no changes in the proportions in which different means of production are used ..., so that no question arises as to the variation or constancy of returns".[15] As in classics, in Sraffa’s 1960 book, relative prices are determined by the conditions of production and not on the basis of the functional connection between returns and quantity produced.[16]  

Sraffa's Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960)was an attempt  is proposed to  to perfect classical economics' theory of value as originally developed by Ricardo and others. He aimed to demonstrate flaws in the mainstream neoclassical theory of value and develop an alternative analysis. In this important work,  Sraffa analyzes a linear production model in which it is possible to determine the relative price structure and one of the two distributive variables (rate of profit or wage), exogenously given the other and the technology.  The value of the capital employed can be known only together with the prices of the goods from which it is made. In essence, Sraffa proves that:

1)                It is not possible to identify a law that simultaneously determines the wage and the rate of profit because: i) the rate of profit can only be determined by setting the wage (or vice versa); ii) it is impossible to measure capital without also determining prices (including the profit), so it is not possible to calculate the profit based on the value of capital (as its remuneration).

2)                It cannot be assumed that, as wages increase, labour is replaced by capital, as the value of the capital depends on the duration of the initial investment; considering capitals of different duration, it may well happen that we prefer to replace capital with labour even if wages increase (so-called "return of   techniques"); consequently unemployment cannot be attributed to the increase in wages.

Sraffa's technique of aggregating capital as "dated inputs of labour" led to a debate known as the Cambridge capital controversy.

Sraffa’s analytical apparatus was used by some followers for the solution to the marxian problem of transforming values into prices of production and for the criticism of the Marxian theory of value. Moreover, as highlighted by Pasinetti, Sraffa’s analysis overcomes the limits of the input-output system of Wassily Leontief, in particular with regard to the effects of technical change.[17]  Pasinetti's approach, based on Sraffa’s theory, has recently been developed by Kurz and Salvadori.[18]

Economists disagree on whether  on the relationship between  Sraffa's work refutes and neoclassical economics. Many post-Keynesian economists use Sraffa's theory critique as justification for abandoning neoclassical analysis and exploring other models of economic behaviour. Others see his work as compatible with neoclassical economics as developed in modern general equilibrium models, or as unable to determine a long-period position, just like the Walrasian approach. Others still argue that the importance of Sraffa's economics is that it provides a new framework for how we understand capitalist economies that does not fall back on the arguably unrealistic assumptions of neoclassical economics.

Nonetheless, Sraffa's work, particularly his interpretation of Ricardo and his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960), is seen as the starting point of the neo-Ricardian school in the 1960s. His approach has been described as serving "to help judge Ricardo's editor and to illuminate the unity in [his] scientific vision, from before 1926 until death in 1983" [REPETITION] .

Personal connections

Sraffa was a close friend of Italian Marxist thinker Antonio Gramsci and [DELETED TO AVOID REPETTION]  was instrumental in securing Antonio Gramsci's Prison Notebooks from the Fascist authorities after the latter's death in 1937.

In 1924, Gramsci published a letter from Sraffa titled "Problems of today and of tomorrow", (without signing, signed S.),  In this letter, Sraffa emphasizes the function of bourgeois opposition in the struggle against fascism and the importance of democratic institutions for the social and political development of the proletariat. Seeing the Italian Communist Party as weak, Sraffa recommended collaboration with the bourgeois opposition to fascism. In his answer, Gramsci rejected this suggestion, but he followed Sraffa’s advice several years later.

Norman Malcolm famously credits Sraffa with providing Ludwig Wittgenstein with the conceptual break that founded the Philosophical Investigations, by means of a rude gesture on Sraffa's part:

Wittgenstein was insisting that a proposition and what that which it describes must have the same 'logical form', the same 'logical multiplicity'. Sraffa made a gesture, familiar to Neapolitans as meaning something like disgust or contempt, of brushing the underneath of his chin with an outward sweep of the finger-tips of one hand. And he asked: 'What is the logical form of that?'

In the introduction to Philosophical Investigations, Wittgenstein mentions discussions with Sraffa over many years and says: "I am indebted to this stimulus for the most consequential ideas in this book". However, Sraffa broke off his weekly conversations with Wittgenstein in 1946 over despite the latter's protests; and when the philosopher said he would talk about anything Sraffa wanted, "'Yes', Sraffa replied, 'but in your way'".

Sraffa and Wittgenstein influenced each other deeply. They continually corresponded and discussed each other in their journals and notebooks [IMPRECISE REGARDING TO SRAFFA]. Both authors were dealing with a form of positivism dominant in their respective disciplines, economics and philosophy [IMPRECISE WITH REGARD TO SRAFFA] . While Wittgenstein made his famous turn from the Tractatus Logico-Philosophicus to the Philosophical Investigations wherein he jettisoned the previous idea that the world comprised an atomistic set of propositional facts for the notion that meaning derives from its use within a holistic self-enclosed system. Analogously, Sraffa was rebutting the neoclassical paradigm which was similarly atomistic, and individualistic and derivational (see criticisms of neoclassical economics). While there are disputes about how to interpret Sraffa,  falling primarily into the neoclassical camp of Paul Samuelson and the neo-Ricardian of Pierangelo Garegnani [REPETIVE AND IMPRECISE] none dispute Sraffa's influence. and it can be argued that Sraffa's critique of neoclassical economics is analogous to that of Wittgenstein's of philosophy, in that Sraffa sought to replace the individualistic and positivistic account of price as the result of an equilibration [EQUILIBRIUM, SIC!] of supply and demand, for instead as price serving a social function, namely to reproduce a stationary or expanding economy given a distribution of income. [VERY IMPRECISE AS FAR AS SRAFFA IS CONCERNED][clarification needed (see talk)]

Other biographical notes

After the publication of  Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Sraffa's thought became the subject of a great debate.

Sraffa was described as a shy and very reserved intelligent [IT IS EVIDENT FROM  ALL THIS ENTRY AND THEREFORE REDUNDANT]  man who was devoted to study and books. He was a great researcher of the rarest editions and famous was the discovery with Keynes of a small but important libretto by David Hume was famous  ( An abstract of A treatise of human nature, 1740). He left his own library to the at Wren Library of Trinity College : the online catalogue [2] is over 7,000 volumes (7085 records).

A popular anecdote claims that Sraffa made successful long-term investments in Japanese government bonds that he bought the day after the nuclear bombing on Hiroshima and Nagasaki. Another version of this is that Sraffa bought the bonds during the war when they were trading at distressed prices as he was convinced that Japan would honour its obligations (Nicholas Kaldor, pp. 66–67).

In 1961, before when the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel had not yet been created, he was awarded the Söderströmska Gold Medal by the Royal Swedish Academy of Science. In 1972, he was awarded an honorary doctorate by Sorbonne and in 1976 received another one from Madrid's Complutense University.

Bibliography

Principal works by Piero Sraffa

•   Sraffa, Piero,  “Monetary inflation in Italy during and after the war”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 17, No. 1 (March 1993), pp. 7-26; Engl. translation by W.J. Harcourt and C. Sardoni of “L’inflazione monetaria in Italia durante e dopo la Guerra,  Milan, Premiata Scuola Tip. Salesiana, 1920; reprint in Economia Politica, XI, n.2, August 1994, pp. 163-196.

• _____, “The Bank Crisis in Italy”, The Economic Journal, 1922, 36 (126) (June), pp. 178-197.

•_____, “The current situation of Italian banks”, Manchester Guardian Commercial,

1922, 7 December.

•_____, “Sulle relazioni tra costo e quantità prodotta”, Annali di economia, II, 1925, pp. 277-328;

English translation by A. Roncaglia and J. Eatwel, “On the relations between cost and quantity produced”, in L.L. Pasinetti (ed.), Italian Economic Papers, vol. III, Il Mulino – Oxford University Press, 1998, pp. 323-363.

•  _____,  "The Laws of Returns under Competitive Conditions", Economic Journal, 1926, 36(144), pp. 535–50.

•DH Robertson, Piero Sraffa and GF Shove, "Increasing Returns and the Representative

Firm ", The Economic Journal, Vol. 40, No. 157 (March, 1930), pp. 79-116.

•Piero Sraffa and L. Einaudi, "An Alleged Correction of Ricardo", The Quarterly Journal of

Economics , Vol. 44, No. 3 (May, 1930), pp. 539-545.

• _____, “Dr. Hayek on Money and Capital”, The Economic Journal, 1932, 42: 42–53.

•_____, “A Rejoinder”, The Economic Journal, 1932, 42 (June): 249–51.

• _____, “Malthus on Public Works”, The Economic Journal, 1955, 259 (Sept.): 543-544.

• _____, “Introduction to David Ricardo”, Works and Correspondence, in P. Sraffa and M.H. Dobb, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1951-1955 (vols. IX) and 1973 (vol. XI, indexes), vol. I: pp. XIII-

LXII.

·                    _____ and M.H. Dobb, editors (1951–1973). The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo. Cambridge University Press, 11 vols. Online at the Online Library of Liberty.

·                    _____, 1960, Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities: Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. Cambridge University Press. Preview.

References

·        D'Orlando, Fabio (2005). "Will the Classical-type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory?", in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27(4), pp. 633–654

·        Eatwell, John (1984). "Piero Sraffa: Seminal Economic Theorist." Science and Society, 48(2), pp. 211–216. JSTOR 40402578. Reprinted in Piero Sraffa: Critical Assessments, J. Wood J. C. Wood, 1995, v. 1, pp. 74–79.

·        Eatwell, John and Panico, C. (1987 [2008]). "Sraffa, Piero", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 3, pp. 445–52.

·        Enciclopedia Treccani, "Sraffa, Piero in "Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero: Economia"". www.treccani.it.

·        Harcourt, Geoffrey C., “Sraffa, Piero (1898–1983)”, Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford University Press, 2004.

·        Hayek, F.A. (1931a),  "Reflection on the pure theory of money of Mr. JM Keynes," Economic 11 , S. 270–95 (1931).

·        Hayek, FA. (1931b)  Prices and Production , (London: Routledge, 1931).

·        Hicks, John (1939), The Foundations of Welfare Economics, pp. 696–712 in Economic Journal, IL, December 1939

Kurz, Heinz D. (2000) "Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics" (2000)

·        Kurz Heinz D. and Salvadori Neri (1907), Theory of production. A long-period analysis, Cambridge University Press.

·        Monk, R. (1991),  Ludwig Wittgenstein

  • Morroni. Mario (1998a), Decreasing returns, in Kurz H.D. e Salvadori N. (eds), The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics. A-K, vol. I, Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Morroni, Mario (1999b), Increasing returns, in Kurz H.D. e Salvadori N. (eds), The Elgar Companion to Classical Economics. A-K, vol. I, Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Norman, Malcolm,  “Ludwig Wittgenstein: A Memoir”, pp. 58–59.
  • L'Ordine Nuovo (PDF). www.centrogramsci.it. Retrieved 2019-06-11.

·        Panico, Carlo, Salvadori, Neri (1994), "Sraffa, Marshall and the problem of returns", European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, vol. 1, n. 2, pp. 323-343.

·        Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1977),  Lectures on the theory of production, MacMillan, London.

·        Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1998), “Piero Sraffa: An Italian economist at Cambridge”, in L.L. Pasinetti (ed.), Italian Economic Papers, vol. III, Il Mulino – Oxford University Press, 1998, pp. 365-382.

·        Potier,  Jean-Pierre (1991). Piero Sraffa, Unorthodox Economist (1898–1983): A Biographical Essay (1898–1983: a Biographical Essay). ISBN 978-0-415-05959-6.

·        Pilkington, Philip (2014) "The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview: A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism", Fixing the Economists, April 29th http://fixingtheeconomists.wordpress.com/2014/04/29/the-sraffian-versus-the-marginalist-worldview-a-strong-case-for-academic-pluralism/

·        Samuelson,  Paul A ([1987] 2008). "Sraffian economics." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.

  • Sinha A., "Sraffa and the Later Wittgenstein." Contributions to Political Economy, 2009 Vol. 28, Issue 1, pp. 47–69.
  • Sinha A., "Sraffa's Contributions to the Methodology of Economics." Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics, January 2015 vol. 27 no. 133–48.

·        web.archive.org. (2000) "Piero SRAFFA". 2 September 2000. Archived from the original on 2000-09-02.

Notes

Potier (1991). Piero Sraffa, Unorthodox Economist (1898–1983): A Biographical Essay (1898–1983: a Biographical Essay). ISBN 978-0-415-05959-6.

2  The participants of the Symposium 1930 in the Economic Journal were more concerned with how increasing returns can be made compatible with competition than with what are the consequences of increasing returns in the real world. Hicks (1939, The Foundations of Welfare Economics, pp. 696–712 in Economic Journal, IL, December 1939) concluded that Sraffa's view has destructive consequences for the major part of economic theory.

G. C. Harcourt, 'Sraffa, Piero (1898–1983)', Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford University Press,( 2004).

4 Eatwell (1984). "Piero Sraffa: Seminal Economic Theorist." Science and Society, 48(2), pp. 211–216. JSTOR 40402578 Reprinted in Piero Sraffa: Critical Assessments, J. Wood J. C. Wood, 1995, v. 1, pp. 74–79.

5 D'Orlando (2005). "Will the Classical-type Approach Survive Sraffian Theory?", in Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 27(4), pp. 633–654

6 Philip Pilkington. "The Sraffian Versus the Marginalist Worldview: A Strong Case for Academic Pluralism", Fixing the Economists, April 29th( 2014), http://fixingtheeconomists.wordpress.com/2014/04/29/the-sraffian-versus-the-marginalist-worldview-a-strong-case-for-academic-pluralism/

 Samuelson ([1987] 2008). "Sraffian economics." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 2nd Edition. Abstract.

8 Eatwell and  Panico (1987 [2008]),  pp. 445–52.

"L'Ordine Nuovo" (PDF). www.centrogramsci.it. Retrieved 2019-06-11.

10 www.treccani.it.,  "Sraffa, Piero”  in Il Contributo italiano alla storia del Pensiero: Economia".

11  Norman pp. 58–59.

12. Monk (1991) p. 487.

13 Sinha (2009).

14 Kurz (2000).

15 Sinha (2015).

16. web.archive.org."Piero SRAFFA". 2 September 2000.


Further reading

·      Keen, Steve  Debunking Economics: The Naked Emperor of the Social Sciences (2001, Pluto Press Australia) ISBN 1-86403-070-4.

·       Kurz, Heinz D. (Ed.) Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Contribution to Economics (2000, Cambridge University Press) ISBN 0-521-58089-7.

·      Ranchetti, Fabio, "On the Relationship between Sraffa and Keynes", in T. Cozzi e R. Marchionatti (eds.), Piero Sraffa's Political Economy: A Centenary Estimate, Routledge, London, 2001.

·      Ranchetti, Fabio, "Communication and intellectual integrity. The correspondence between Keynes and Sraffa", in M.C. Marcuzzo e A. Rosselli (eds.), Economists in Cambridge, Routledge, London, 2005, pp. 119–148.

·      Vianello, Ferdinando [1988], "A critique of Professor Goodwin's Critique of Sraffa", in: Ricci, G. and Velupillai, K. (eds.), Growth, Cycles and Multisectoral Economics: the Goodwin Tradition, Berlin, Sringer-Verlag, ISBN 978-3-540-19467-5.

·      Vianello, Ferdinando [1989], "Effective Demand and the Rate of Profits: Some Thoughts on Marx, Kalecki and Sraffa", in: Sebastiani, M. (ed.), Kalecki's Relevance Today, London, Macmillan, ISBN 978-0-312-02411-6.

DA AGGIUNGERE A FURTHER READING


·     Baranzini, M., Mirante A., A Compendium of Italian Economists at Oxbridge Contributions to the Evolution of Economic Thinking, Palgrave Macmillan, London, 2016.

  • Bellino E., "On Sraffa's Standard commodity", Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 28, 121-32, 2004.
  • Bharadwaj K., "Piero Sraffa (1898-1983)", Social Scientist Vol. 11, No. 10 (Oct., 1983), pp. 3–7.
  • Chiodi G., Ditta L. (eds), Sraffa or an Alternative Economics, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, 2008.
  • Ciccone R., Gehrke C., Mongiovi G. (eds), Sraffa and Modern Economics, Volume I, Routledge, 2011.
  • de Vivo G., "Sraffa's path to Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. An interpretation", Contributions to Political Economy , 2003, 22(1): 1-25.
  • Eatwell J.,  Panico C., "Sraffa, Piero", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 1987, v. 3: pp. 445–52.
  • Garegnani P., "Sraffa's Revival of Marxist Economic Theory", New Left Review, 1978, I/112.
  • Garegnani P., "Piero Sraffa", Cambridge Journal of Economics, 8(1), 1984, 8 (1): pp. 1–2.
  • Garegnani P., "On Sraffa's Contribution to Economic Theory", in G.R. Feiwel (ed.), Joan Robinson and Modern Economic Theory, Macmillan, London, 1989.
  • Garegnani P., "Sraffa: Classical versus Marginalist Analysis" and Reply to discussants, in K. Bharadwaj and B. Schefold (eds) Essays on Piero Sraffa, Unwin Hyman, London, 1990.
  • Garegnani P., "Sraffa's Price Equations: Stationary Economy or Normal Positions?", in S. Bohm, C. Gehrke, H.D. Kurz, R. Sturn (eds), Is there Progress in Economics? Knowledge, Truth and the History of Economic Thought, Edward Elgar, Northampton, 2002.
  • Garegnani P., "On a turning point in Sraffa's theoretical and interpretative position in the late 1920s", Journal of History of Economic Thought, 2005, 12(3), pp. 453–492.
  • Garegnani P., "Professor Samuelson on Sraffa and the classical economists", European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2007, 14(2), pp. 181–242.
  • Harcourt G.C., "On the Influence of Piero Sraffa on the Contributions of Joan Robinson to Economic Theory", The Economic Journal 96 Supplement: Conference Papers, 1986, pp. 96–108.
  • Ingrao B., Ranchetti F., "Hayek and Cambridge: dialogue and contention. The correspondence with Kahn, Kaldor, J. Robinson and Sraffa", in M.C. Marcuzzo, A. Rosselli (eds), Economists in Cambridge, Routledge, London, 2005, pp. 392–413.
  • Kurz H.D., Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2000.
  • Kurz H.D., Pasinetti L.L., Salvadori N. (eds) Piero Sraffa: The Man and the Scholar, Exploring his Unpublished Papers, Routledge, London, 2008.
  • Kurz H.D. e Salvadori N. "Sraffa and the mathematicians: Frank Ramsey and Alister Watson", in T. Cozzi and R. Marchionatti (eds), Piero Sraffa's Political Economy: A Centenary Estimate, Routledge, London, 2001, pp. 254–84.
  • Marcuzzo M.C., "Piero Sraffa at the University of Cambridge", European Journal for the History of Economic Thought, 2005 12(3): 425-52.
  • Mongiovi G., "Piero Sraffa" in Arestis P., Sawyer M.C. (eds) A biographical dictionary of dissenting economists, Edward Elgar, Aldershot, 1992.
  • Naldi N., "Some notes on Piero Sraffa's biography. 1917-1927", Review of Political Economy, 1998, vol.10, n.4, pp. 493–515.
  • Naldi N., "The friendship between Piero Sraffa and Antonio Gramsci in the years 1919-1927", European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2000, vol.7, n.1, pp. 79–114.
  • Naldi N., "Piero Sraffa's early approach to political economy: from the ‘gymnasium, to the beginning of his academic career", in Cozzi T., Marchionatti R., (eds), Piero Sraffa's Political Economy: A Centenary Estimate, Routledge, London, 2001.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "Sraffa, Piero", International Encyclopedia of the Social Science, Vol. 18 - Biographical Supplement, The Free Press, New York, 1979, pp. 736–739.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "Sraffa's Circular Process and the Concept of Vertical Integration", Political Economy - Studies in the Surplus Approach, 1986, vol.1, pp. 3–16; rist. in Bharadwaj K., Schefold B. (eds), Essays on Piero Sraffa, Unwin Hyman, London, 1990, pp. 229–239.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "Sraffa on Income Distribution", Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1988, vol.12, pp. 135–138.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "Continuity and Change in Sraffa's Thought–An Archival Excursus", in Cozzi T., Marchionatti R. (eds), Piero Sraffa's Political Economy – A centenary estimate, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2001, pp. 139–156.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "The Sraffa-enigma", The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2005, vol. 12, n. 3, pp. 373–378.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "Paul Samuelson and Piero Sraffa - Two prodigious minds at the opposite poles", in Szenberg M., Ramrattan L., Gottesman A.A. (eds), Samuelsonian Economics and the Twenty-First Century, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2006, pp. 146–164.
  • Pasinetti L.L., "The Sraffa-enigma: Introduction", in Kurz H.D., Pasinetti L.L. e Salvadori N. (eds), Piero Sraffa: The Man and the Scholar, Exploring his Unpublished Papers, Routledge, London, 2008, pp. 1–6.
  • Pasinetti L.L., Keynes and the Cambridge Keynesians. A ‘Revolution in Economics' to be accomplished, Cambridge UP, Cambridge, 2007.
  • Pivetti M., "On Sraffa's ‘cost & surplus' concept of wages and its policy implications", Rivista Italiana degli Economisti, 1999/2.
  • Porta P.L., "Joan Robinson and Piero Sraffa", Rivista internazionale di scienze economiche e commerciali, 1995, 42 (9), pp. 681–9.
  • Roncaglia A., Piero Sraffa, Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, 2009.
  • Schefold B., "Von Neumann and Sraffa: Mathematical Equivalence and Conceptual Difference", Economic Journal, 1980, 90 (357): 140-56.
  • Schefold B., "Piero Sraffa 1898-1983", Economic Journal, 1996 (Sept.), Vol. 106, No. 438: 1314-1325.
  • Sen A., "Sraffa, Wittgenstein, and Gramsci", Journal of Economic Literature, 2003, 41(4): 1240-1255.
  • Sinha A., A Revolution in Economic Theory. The Economics of Piero Sraffa, Palgrave Macmillan, London, 2016.
  • Steedman I., Marx after Sraffa, New Left Books, London, 1977.
  • Steedman I., Sraffian Economics, Edwar Elgar, Aldershot, 1988.
  • Stigler G.J., "Sraffa's Ricardo", The American Economic Review, 1953 (Sept.), 43(4): 586-99.


External links

Wikiquote has quotations related to: Piero Sraffa

·                    Piero Sraffa Archives homepage at Trinity College, Cambridge. Contains an online catalogue of Sraffa's personal and professional papers.

·                    Piero Sraffa (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities — Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory (PDF). Bombay: Vora & Co., Publishers Bvt. Ltd.

·                    Roncaglia, Alessandro (2009). Piero Sraffa (PDF). Great Thinkers in Economics. Palgrave Macmillan. OCLC 956749156.

Authority control ·                     BIBSYS: 90174488

·                     BNF: cb11925385h (data)

·                     GND: 118616463

·                     ISNI: 0000 0001 1467 0791

·                     LCCN: n79054507

·                     NDL: 00457396

·                     NKC: mzk2004231292

·                     ICCU: IT\ICCU\CFIV\008360

·                     SNAC: w6kj3gn2

·                     SUDOC: 02897218X

·                     VIAF: 7397238

·                     WorldCat Identities (via VIAF): 7397238

·                    Business and economics portal

·                    Italy portal

·                    Biography portal

Categories:

·                    1898 births

·                    1983 deaths

·                    People from Turin

·                    Post-Keynesian economists

·                    Italian agnostics

·                    Italian economists

·                    Italian Jews

·                    Italian pacifists

·                    Italian socialists

·                    Jewish agnostics

·                    Jewish scientists

·                    Alumni of the London School of Economics

·                    Fellows of Trinity College, Cambridge

·                    Academic staff of the University of Perugia

·                    Socialist economists

Related items

• Alternative interpretations of the Marxian theory of value

• Production of goods by means of goods

• Neoricardian school

• Claudio Napoleoni

• Pierangelo Garegnani

• Luigi Pasinetti

• Fernando Vianello

Other projects

Wikiquote contains quotes from or about Piero Sraffa

External links

• Sraffa Piero the voice in Treccani.it The Italian Encyclopedia. URL visited on February 11th

2013.

• Profile of Piero Sraffa on the site History of Economic Thought

• Piero Sraffa archives homepage at Trinity College, Cambridge. Contains a

online catalog of his personal and professional documents.

• Sraffa and the context. Intervention by Giorgio Lunghini at the international conference on Sraffa

promoted by the Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei.

• Luigi Pasinetti, Continuity and Change in Sraffa's Thought. An Archival Excursus , in T.

Cozzi and R. Marchionatti, Piero Sraffa's Political Economy. A Centenary Estimate ,

Routledge, London and New York, 2001, pp. 139-156.

• Piero Sraffa - Production of commodities ( PDF ), on laprimaradice.myblog.it .

• Piero Sraffa by Alessandro Roncaglia ( PDF ), on digamo.free.fr .





[1] Pasinetti (1998, p. 370).

[2] Sraffa (1925).

[3] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, p. 324).

[4] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, pp. 324-325).

[5] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, p. 326); cf. Morroni (1998a, p. 210)

[6] Sraffa (1926, p. 539); cf. Morroni (1998a, p. 209; 1998b, p. 402).

[7] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, pp. 358-359; 1926, pp. 538-539); Morroni (1998a, p. 210).

[8] Sraffa (1926, p. 540); Morroni (1998a, p. 221).

[9] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, pp. 361-362; 1926, p. 540); cf. Morroni (1985, p. 109; 1998b, pp. 402-403).

[10] Sraffa (1926, p. 541).

[11] Sraffa (1925 in 1998, p. 363).

[12] Hayek (1931a; 1931b).

[13] Sraffa (1932).

[14] Morroni (1998a, p. 212).

[15] Sraffa, 1960, pp. v-vi; cf. Panico and Salvadori (1994, pp. 324 ff.).

[16] Morroni (1998a, p. 212).

[17] Pasinetti (1977).

[18] Kurz and Salvadoti (1997).