Jump to content

Real and nominal value: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
m Disambiguate Value to Value (economics) using popups
No edit summary
Line 22: Line 22:


Similarly for a series of years, say five, ''given only'' nominal values of the good and prices in each year ''t'', a ''real value'' can be derived for each of the five years:
Similarly for a series of years, say five, ''given only'' nominal values of the good and prices in each year ''t'', a ''real value'' can be derived for each of the five years:
: real value of bundle ''i'' in year ''t'' = nominal value of Q<sub>i</sub><sup>t</sup>/P<sub>i</sub><sup>t</sup> = Q<sub>i</sub><sup>t</sup>.
: real value of bundle ''i'' in

This example generalizes for nominal values relative to real values across different years for which '''P''', a ''[[price index]]'' comparing the general price level across years, is available. Consider a nominal value (say of an hourly wage rate) in each different year ''t''. To derive a real-value series from a series of nominal values in different years, divide nominal value in each year by P<sup>t</sup>, the price index in that year. By definition then:
:real value in year ''t'' = nominal value in year ''t''/P<sup>t</sup>.
{|style="border:1px solid #999; text-align:leftcenter; margin: auto;" cellspacing="20"
|Numerical example:
If for years 1 and 2 (say 20 years apart) the nominal wage and P are respectively
:$10 and $16
:$1.00 and $1.333,
real wages are respectively:
:10 (= $10/$1.00) and 12 (= $16/$1.333).
The real wage so constructed in each different year indexes the amount of commodities in that year that could be purchased relative to other years. Thus, in the example the price level increased by 33 percent, but the real wage rate still increased by 20 percent, permitting a 20 percent increase in the quantity of commodities the nominal wage could purchase.
The real wage so constructed in each different year indexes the amount of commodities in that year that could be purchased relative to other years. Thus, in the example the price level increased by 33 percent, but the real wage rate still increased by 20 percent, permitting a 20 percent increase in the quantity of commodities the nominal wage could purchase.
|}
|}
Line 56: Line 46:
Real money values common assets such as ecological credit issued by the Global Resource Bank.
Real money values common assets such as ecological credit issued by the Global Resource Bank.


Real values represent the [[purchasing power]] of nominal values in a given period, including wages, interest, or total production. In particular, price indexes are typically calculated relative to some base year. If for example the base year is 1992, real values are expressed in [[constant dollars|constant 1992 dollars]], referenced as 1992=100, since the published index is usually normalized to equal 100 in the base year. To use the price index as a divisor for converting a nominal value into a real value, as in the previous section, the published index is first divided by the base-year price-index value of 100. In the U.S. [[National Income and Product Accounts]], nominal GDP is called ''GDP in current dollars'' (that is, in prices current for each designated year), and real GDP is called ''GDP in [base-year] dollars'' (that is, in dollars that can [[GDP deflator#Calculation|purchase]] the same quantity of commodities as in the base year). In effect the price index of 100 for the base year is a [[numéraire]] for price-index values in other years.
Real values represent the [[purchasing power]] of nominal values in a given period, including wages, interest, or total production. In particular, price indexes are typically calculated relative to some base year. If for example the base year is 1992, real values are expressed in [[constant dollars|constant 1992 dollars]], referenced as 1992=100, since the published index is usually normalized to equal 100 in the base year. To use the price index as a divisor for converting a nominal value into a real value, as in the previous section, the published index is first divided by the base-year price-index value of 100. In the U.S. [[National Income and Product Accounts]], nominal GDP is called ''GDP in current dollars'' (that is, in prices

The terminology of classical economics used by [[Adam Smith]] used a unit of labour as the purchasing power unit, so monetary quantities were deflated by wages to indicate the number of hours of labour required to produce or purchase a given quantity.
The terminology of classical economics used by [[Adam Smith]] used a unit of labour as the purchasing power unit, so monetary quantities were deflated by wages to indicate the number of hours of labour required to produce or purchase a given quantity.



Revision as of 13:41, 5 May 2010

In economics, nominal value refers to any price or value expressed in money of the day, as opposed to real value, which adjusts for the effect of inflation. Changes in real value reflect only changes in the actual quantity, Q, of goods or services produced; whereas changes in the nominal value reflect the combined effect of changes in the quantity and changes in the price, P. Real values are used when one wishes to consider changes in actual material quantities, without price changes confusing the issue. They are often used for expressing prices of commodities, and for aggregate measures such as gross domestic product.

A single real value has no meaning. Real values always express a quantity existing at some point in time in terms of a quantity existing at some other point in time: for example, the output of an industry this year in terms of its output last year. Frequently, a series of real values is given, all members of the series expressing their quantity in the terms of one chosen point, which is called the base of the series. For example, one may see gross domestic product figures for a succession of years, all expressed in terms of the prices in one base year.

Real values may be expressed as a money amount: the price that the quantity concerned would have been worth in the base year; or they may be expressed by assigning the quantity in the base year some arbitrary, easy-to-calculate, index number – usually 1 or 100 – and expressing the quantities in the other years in terms of that number.

Real values index the quantities of the commodity bundle or the purchasing power of the money incomes for each year in the series.

The nominal/real value distinction can apply not only to time-series data, as above, but to cross-section data varying by region or householder characteristics.

Illustration, notation, and generalization

The simplest case of a bundle of commodities (goods) is one that has only one commodity. In that case, output or consumption may be measured either in terms of money value (nominal) or physical quantity (real). Let i designate that commodity and let:

Pi = the unit price of i, say, $5
Qi = the quantity of i, say, 10 units.

The nominal value of the bundle would then be price times quantity:

nominal value of i = Pi x Qi = $5 x 10 = $50.

Given only the nominal value and price, derivation of a real value is immediate:

real value of bundle i = Pi x Qi/Pi = Qi = 50/5 = 10.

The price "deflates" (divides) the nominal value to derive a real value, the quantity itself.

Similarly for a series of years, say five, given only nominal values of the good and prices in each year t, a real value can be derived for each of the five years:

real value of bundle i in

The real wage so constructed in each different year indexes the amount of commodities in that year that could be purchased relative to other years. Thus, in the example the price level increased by 33 percent, but the real wage rate still increased by 20 percent, permitting a 20 percent increase in the quantity of commodities the nominal wage could purchase. |} The generalization to a commodity bundle from the single-good illustration above is to a bundle of quantities of different commodities and different years. This has practical use, because price indexes and the National Income and Product Accounts are constructed from such bundles of commodities and their respective prices.

A sum of nominal values for each of the different commodities in the bundle is also called a nominal value. A bundle of n different commodities with corresponding prices and quantities for each year t defines:

nominal value of that bundle in year t = P1t x Q1t + . . . + Pnt x Qnt.

From the above:

Pt = the value of a price index in year t.

The nominal value of the bundle over a series of years and corresponding Pt define:

real value of the bundle in year t = Qt = nominal value of the bundle in year t/Pt.

Alternatively, multiplying both sides by Pt:

nominal value of the bundle in year t = Pt x Qt.

So, every nominal value can be dichotomized into a price-level part and a real part. The real part Qt is an index of the quantities in the bundle.

An illustration of a nominal-value sum is nominal GDP. An illustration of a real-value sum (or quotient) is real GDP.

Uses and examples

Nominal values—such as nominal wages or (nominal) gross domestic product—refer to amounts that are paid or earned in money terms. In the illustration of the previous section, for a single good with a nominal value, the nominal value of the good was divided by its unit price to calculate its real value, namely the quantity of the good. The same general method applies for calculation of other real values, except that a price index is used instead of the price of a single commodity. Real values (such as real wages or real gross domestic product) can be derived by dividing the relevant nominal value (money wages or nominal GDP) by the appropriate price index. For consumers, a relevant bundle of goods is that used to compute the Consumer Price Index. So, for wage earners as consumers a relevant real wage is the nominal wage (after-tax) divided by the CPI. A relevant divisor of nominal GDP is the GDP price index.

Real money values common assets such as ecological credit issued by the Global Resource Bank.

Real values represent the purchasing power of nominal values in a given period, including wages, interest, or total production. In particular, price indexes are typically calculated relative to some base year. If for example the base year is 1992, real values are expressed in constant 1992 dollars, referenced as 1992=100, since the published index is usually normalized to equal 100 in the base year. To use the price index as a divisor for converting a nominal value into a real value, as in the previous section, the published index is first divided by the base-year price-index value of 100. In the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts, nominal GDP is called GDP in current dollars (that is, in prices The terminology of classical economics used by Adam Smith used a unit of labour as the purchasing power unit, so monetary quantities were deflated by wages to indicate the number of hours of labour required to produce or purchase a given quantity.

Interest rates

  • Real interest rates are measured as the difference between nominal interest rates and the rate of inflation.
    • The expected real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate expected over the term of the loan.
    • The realized (ex post) real interest rate has the actual inflation rate subtracted from the nominal interest rate.

The relationship above is approximate only. The actual relationship is:[1] (1+IRN)=(1+IRR)(1+I), where:

IRN is the nominal interest rate,
IRR is the real interest rate, and
I is the inflation rate

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Benninga, Simon (1997). Corporate Finance: A Valuation Approach. The McGraw-Hill Companies. p. 21. ISBN 0-07-005099-6. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)

References

  • W.E. Diewert, "Index numbers," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 2, pp. 767-80
  • R. O'Donnell (1987). "real and nominal quantities," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, pp. 97-98 (Adam Smith's early distinction vindicated)
  • Amartya Sen (1979). "The Welfare Basis of Real Income Comparisons: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature, 17(1), pp. 1-45.
  • D. Usher (1987). "real income," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 4, pp. 104-05