Jump to content

Permanent income hypothesis

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by BasedMises (talk | contribs) at 23:25, 17 June 2021. The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

A Model of the Permanent Income Hypothesis
A model of the Permanent Income Hypothesis

The permanent income hypothesis (often abbreviated PIH) is a model in the field of economics to explain the formation of consumption patterns. It suggests consumption patterns are formed from future expectations and consumption smoothing.[α] The theory was developed by Milton Friedman and published in his A Theory of Consumption Function, published in 1957 and subsequently challenged by Robert Hall's inclusion of rational expectations. Originally applied to consumption and income, the process of future expectations is thought to influence other phenomena. In its simplest form, the hypothesis states changes in permanent income (human capital, property, assets), rather than changes in temporary income (unexpected income), are what drive changes in consumption.

Milton Friedman
Nobel laureate and inventor of the Permanent Income Hypothesis Milton Friedman

The formation of consumption patterns opposite to predictions was an outstanding problem faced by the Keynesian orthodoxy. Friedman's predictions of consumption smoothing, where people spread out transitory changes in income over time, departed from the traditional Keynesian emphasis on a higher marginal propensity to consume[β] out of current income.

Income consists of a permanent (anticipated and planned) component and a transitory (unexpected and surprising) component. In the permanent income hypothesis model, the key determinant of consumption is an individual's lifetime income, not their current income. Unlike permanent income, transitory incomes are volatile.

Background and history

Until A Theory of Consumption Function, the Keynesian absolute income hypothesis and interpretation of the consumption function were the most advanced and sophisticated.[2][3] In its post-war synthesis, the Keynesian perspective was responsible for pioneering many innovations in recession management, economic history, and macroeconomics. Like the neoclassical school that preceded it, early inconsistencies had their roots in socio-political events contrary to the predictions put forward.[3]

The introduction of the absolute income hypothesis is often attributed to John Maynard Keynes, a British economist, who wrote several books which are now the basis for Keynesian economics.[4] The hypothesis put forward by Keynes was accepted and placed into the post–war synthesis. However, inconsistencies were not resolved swiftly, and economists were unable to explain the consistency of the savings rate in the face of rising real incomes (Fig. 1).[3]

Relationship between Saving and Consumption Based on Budget Data[5]
United States (USD)
Date Consumer Units Avg. Income APC MPC
1881–90 Selected wage-earner families $682 .90 .67
1901 Selected wage-earner normal families $651 .92 .68
1917–19 Selected wage-earner families $1,513 .91 .78
1935–36 Nonrelief nonfarm families $1,952 .89 .73
1935–36 Nonrelief farm families $1,259 .87 .57
1941 Urban families $2,865 .92 .79
1941 Farm families $1,680 .83 .57
1944 Urban families $3,411 .82 .57
1947 Urban families $3,323 .92 .78
1950 Nonfarm families $4,084 .91 .73
1950 Spending units of one or more persons $3,220 .92 .75

Fig. 1: Analysis of consumption and income; taken from Friedman (1957)

Before the neoclassical synthesis was established, Keynes and his hypothesis challenged the orthodoxy of neoclassical economics.[3] As a result of the Great Depression, Keynes rapidly became among the leaders of economic thought. His MPC and MPS spending multipliers developed into the absolute income hypothesis (1), and were influential to the government responses to the ensuing depression.[3][6]

(1)

Origins

The American economist Milton Friedman developed the permanent income hypothesis in his 1957 book A Theory of the Consumption Function.[7] In his book, Friedman posits a theory that explained how and why future expectations change consumption.[8]

Friedman's 1957 book created the basis for consumption smoothing. He argued the consumption model, in which outcomes are stochastic,[γ] where consumers face risks and uncertainty to their labor incomes,[δ] complicates interpretations of indifference curves,[11] and causes consumers to spread out or 'smooth' their spending based off of their permanent income, which represents their anticipated income over their lifetimes.[7][8] Friedman explain in A Theory of the Consumption Function how consumers interact with money based off of not just windfall gains, but through their permanent income because consumers will save when they expect their long term income to rise.[7] He writes:[12]

'Yet from another point of view, the assumption seems highly implausible. Will not a man who receives an unexpected windfall use at least some part of it in "riotous living," i.e. in consumption expenditures? Would he be likely to add the whole of it to his wealth? The answer to these questions depends greatly on how "consumption" is defined. The offhand affirmative answer reflects in large measure, I believe, an implicit definition of consumption in terms of purchases, including durable goods, rather than in terms of the value of services. If the latter definition is adopted, as seems highly desirable in applying the hypothesis to empirical data—though unfortunately I have been able to do so to only a limited extent—much that one classifies offhand as consumption is reclassified as savings. Is not the windfall likely to be used for the purchase of durable goods? Or, to put it differently, is not the timing of the replacement of durable goods and of additions to the stock of such goods likely to some extent to be adjusted so as to coincide with windfalls?'

— A Theory of Consumption Function

Theoretical considerations

In his theory, John Maynard Keynes supported economic policy makers by his argument emphasizing their capability of macroeconomic fine tuning. For Keynes, consumption expenditures are linked to disposable income by a parameter called the marginal propensity to consume (the amount per dollar consumers are willing to spend; ).[13] Since the marginal propensity to consume itself is a function of income, it is also true that additional increases in disposable income lead to diminishing increases in consumption expenditures. It must be stressed that the relation characterized by substantial stability links current consumption expenditures to current disposable income—and, on these grounds, a considerable leeway is provided for aggregate demand stimulation, since a change in income immediately results in a multiplied shift in aggregate demand (this is the essence of the Keynesian case of the multiplier effect). The same is true of tax cut policies. According to the basic theory of Keynes, governments are always capable of countercyclical fine tuning of macroeconomic systems through demand management, although Friedman disputes this, arguing in a 1961 journal article that Keynesian macroeconomic fine tuning will succumb to 'long and variable lags.'[14]

Model of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption, b is the MPC, and Yd is disposable income.
Model of the consumption function, where a is autonomous consumption, b is the MPC, and Yd is disposable income.

The permanent income hypothesis questions this ability of governments. However, it is also true that permanent income theory is concentrated mainly on long run dynamics and relations, while Keynes focused primarily on short run considerations.[15] Friedman's argument, which challenged the use of fiscal policy in smoothing out business cycles,[16] was challenged by stressing the relation between consumption and disposable income still follows (more or less) the mechanism supposed by Keynes.[2][17]

Friedman starts elaborating his theory under the assumption of complete certainty. Under such circumstances, for Friedman, two motives exist for a consumer unit to spend more or less on consumption than its income: The first is to smooth its consumption expenditures through appropriate timing of borrowing and lending; and the second is either to realize interest earnings on deposits if the relevant rate of interest is positive, or to benefit from borrowing if the interest rate is negative.[18]

According to the PIH, the distribution of consumption across consecutive periods is the result of an optimizing method by which each consumer tries to maximize his utility. At the same time, whatever ratio of income one devotes to consumption in each period, all these consumption expenditures are allocated in the course of an optimization process—that is, consumer units try to optimize not only across periods but within each period.[2][7]

Calculation of income and consumption

Friedman's 1957 book also made an argument for an entirely new way of calculating income (income is represented by the variable ) by differentiating between transitory and permanent income (which was also taken to include ordinal elements like human capital and talents).[19] In A Theory of Consumption Function, Friedman develops: as a formula. In an earlier study, Friedman, Kuznets (1945), he makes the case for a similar conception of income:[20]

'The dichotomy between permanent and transitory components of a man's income, as was noted above, necessarily does violence to the facts. An accurate description of the factors determining a man's income must substitute a continuum for the dichotomy. This continuum is bounded at one extreme by "truly" permanent factors—those that affect a man's income throughout his career— and at the other by the "truly" transitory—those that affect his income only during a single time unit, where a time unit is the shortest period during which it seems desirable to measure income, in our case, a year, but conceivably a month, a week, a day, an hour, or even a minute. Between these extremes fall what may be called "quasi-permanent" factors, factors whose effects neither disappear at once nor last throughout a man's career. The quasi permanent factors can be ordered according to the length of time during which their effects persist: two-year factors, three-year factors, etc. A man's income can then be conceived as the sum of the parts attributable to each set of factors:

Income in any year =

permanent component

+ quasi-permanent component

+ transitory component.'

— Incomes from Independent Professional Practice

Friedman also developed a consumption formula, , with meaning the permanent component of consumption, with being the transitory component. Friedman also drew a distinction between and . Transitory consumption can be interpreted as surprising or unexpected bills, such as a high water bill, or unexpected doctor's visit, which, in Friedman's mind, cannot be spurred by , because unexpected or 'surprise' consumption is not often financed through windfall gains.[7]

Simple model

Consider a (potentially infinitely lived) consumer who maximizes his expected lifetime utility from the consumption of a stream of goods between periods and , as determined by one period utility function . In each period , he receives an income , which he can either spend on a consumption good or save in the form of an asset that pays a constant real interest rate in the next period.[21]

The utility of consumption in future periods is discounted at the rate . Finally, let denote expectation conditional on the information available in period . Formally, the consumer's problem is then

subject to

Assuming the utility function is quadratic, and that , the optimal consumption choice of the consumer is governed by the Euler equation

Given a finite time horizon of length , we set with the understanding the consumer spends all his wealth by the end of the last period. Solving the consumer's budget constraint forward to the last period, we determine the consumption function is given by

(2)

Over an infinite time horizon, we instead impose a no Ponzi game condition, which prevents the consumer from continuously borrowing and rolling over his debt to future periods, by requiring

The resulting consumption function is then

(3)

Both expressions (2) and (3) capture the essence of the permanent income hypothesis: current consumption is determined by a combination of current non human wealth and human capital wealth . The fraction of total wealth consumed today further depends on the interest rate and the length of the time horizon over which the consumer is optimizing.[21]

Liquidity constraints

Some have attempted to improve Friedman's original hypothesis by including liquidity constraints, most notably Christopher D. Carroll.[8][22]

Empirical evidence

Observations, recorded from 1888 to 1941, of stagnant average propensity to consume in the face of rising real incomes provide strong evidence for the existence of the permanent income hypothesis.[23] An early test of the permanent income hypothesis was reported by Robert Hall in 1978, and, assuming rational expectations, finds consumption follows a martingale sequence.[24] Hall & Mishkin (1982) analyze data from 2,000 households and find consumption responds much more strongly to permanent than to transitory movements of income, and reinforce the compatibility of the PIH with 80% of households in the sample.[25] Ben Bernanke (1984) finds 'no evidence against the permanent income hypothesis' when looking at data on automobile consumption.[26]

Median American household spending
Median American household spending

In contrast, Flavin (1981) finds consumption is very sensitive to transitory income shocks ('excess sensitivity'),[27] while Mankiw & Shapiro (1985) dispute these findings, arguing that Flavin's test specification (which assumes income is stationary) is biased towards finding excess sensitivity.[28]

Souleles (1999) uses income tax refunds to test the PIH.[29] Since a refund depends on income in the previous year, it is predictable income and should thus not alter consumption in the year of its receipt.[29] The evidence finds that consumption is sensitive to the income refund, with a marginal propensity to consume between 35 and 60%. Stephens (2003) finds the consumption patterns of social security recipients in the United States is not well explained by the permanent income hypothesis.[30]

Stafford (1974) argues that Friedman's explanation cannot account for market failures such as liquidity constraints.[31] Carroll (1997) and Carroll (2001) dispute this, and adjust the model for limits on borrowing.[8][22] A comprehensive analysis of 3000 tests of the hypothesis provides another explanation. It argues that rejections of the hypothesis are based off publication bias[32] and that after correction, it is consistent with data.[33]

Policy implications

Unresolved inconsistencies explain the failure of transitory Keynesian demand management techniques to achieve its policy targets.[2] In a simple Keynesian framework the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is assumed constant, and so temporary tax cuts can have a large stimulating effect on demand.[34] The PIH framework suggests that a consumer will spread out the gains from a temporary tax cut over a long temporal horizon, and so the stimulus effect will be much smaller. The permanent income hypothesis has evidence supporting such a view, such as Shapiro & Slemrod (2003).[35]

Criticism

Liquidity constraints

Some critics of the permanent income hypothesis, such as Frank Stafford, have criticized the permanent income hypothesis for its lack of liquidity constraints.[31] However, some studies have adapted the hypothesis for certain circumstances and found that the permanent income hypothesis is compatible with liquidity constraints and other market failures unaccounted for in the original hypothesis.[8][22]

Income inequality

There is some evidence that affluent households tend to save more than poorer households. Alvarez-Cuadrado & Van Long (2011) find this evidence contrary to the major tenets of the permanent income hypothesis.[36]

Praise

File:MFriedmanNobel.jpg

Friedman received the 1976 Sveriges Riksbank prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 'For his achievements in the field of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy.'[37] The 'consumption analysis' has been interpreted by Worek (2010) as representing Friedman's contributions in the form of the permanent income hypothesis,[37] while the monetary history and stabilization section has been interpreted to refer to his work on monetary policy and history, and monetarism, which seeks to stabilize a currency, preventing erratic swings, respectively.[37][38]

Austrian School

The Permanent Income Hypothesis has been met with praise from Austrian economists.[39]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Mankiw & Taylor 2006, p. 870.
  2. ^ a b c d Meghir 2004, p. 293–306.
  3. ^ a b c d e Thomas 1985, p. 42–78.
  4. ^ Thomas 1985, p. 160.
  5. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 41.
  6. ^ Keynes 1936, p. 89–134.
  7. ^ a b c d e Friedman 1957, p. 20–37.
  8. ^ a b c d e Carroll 2001, p. 23–45.
  9. ^ Stirzaker 2005, p. 45.
  10. ^ Mankiw & Taylor 2006, p. 155-86.
  11. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 14–17.
  12. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 28.
  13. ^ Keynes 1936, p. 96.
  14. ^ Friedman 1961, p. 447–466.
  15. ^ Keynes 1923, p. 80.
  16. ^ Mankiw 2006, p. 5.
  17. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 38–114.
  18. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 7.
  19. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 21.
  20. ^ Friedman & Kuznets 1945, p. 352.
  21. ^ a b Ireland 1995, p. 49–63.
  22. ^ a b c Carroll 1997, p. 1–55.
  23. ^ Friedman 1957, p. 38–43.
  24. ^ Hall 1978, p. 971–987.
  25. ^ Hall & Mishkin 1982, p. 461–81.
  26. ^ Bernanke 1984, p. 587–614.
  27. ^ Flavin 1981, p. 974–1009.
  28. ^ Mankiw & Shapiro 1984, p. 165–174.
  29. ^ a b Souleles 1999, p. 947–958.
  30. ^ Stephens 2003, p. 406–422.
  31. ^ a b Stafford 1974, p. 195–196.
  32. ^ Runkle 1991, p. 73–98.
  33. ^ Havranek & Sokolova 2020, p. 97–122.
  34. ^ Lee 1975, p. 407–417.
  35. ^ Shapiro & Slemrod 2003, p. 381–396.
  36. ^ Alvarez-Cuadrado & Van Long 2011, p. 1489–1501.
  37. ^ a b c Worek 2010, p. 221.
  38. ^ Forder & Monnery 2019, p. 130–145.
  39. ^ Mulligan 2014, p. 344–346.
  1. ^ The term "consumption smoothing" refers to the tendency of consumers to "smooth out" consumption over their lifetimes; effectively, consumers spread out consumption over time because they want to guarantee stability and prevent diminishing marginal utility from decreasing their utility
  2. ^ The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) represents how much of a dollar a consumer spends or consumes, whereas the marginal propensity to save (MPS) represents how much of a dollar a consumer saves; these units are tracking marginal decision making[1]
  3. ^ Stochastic refers to the property of being well described by a random probability distribution[9]
  4. ^ Unlike capital (k), labor inputs are not fixed in the short term[10]

References