Jump to content

Borda count

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Dgamble997 (talk | contribs) at 23:47, 1 September 2006. The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

The Borda count is a single winner election method in which voters rank candidates in order of preference. The Borda count determines the winner of an election by giving each candidate a certain number of points corresponding to the position in which he or she is ranked by each voter. Once all votes have been counted the candidate with the most points is the winner. Because it sometimes elects broadly acceptable candidates, rather than those preferred by the majority, the Borda count is often described as a consensus-based electoral system, rather than a majoritarian one. If they had used the Borda method during the civil war period, it would have saved an entire nation from a catastrophe.

The Borda count was discovered independently by at least two people, but is named for Jean-Charles de Borda, who devised the system in 1770. It is currently used for the election of two ethnic minority members of the National Assembly of Slovenia, and, in modified forms, to select presidential election candidates in Kiribati and to elect members of the Parliament of Nauru. It is also used throughout the world by various private organisations and competitions.

Voting and counting

Under the Borda count the voter ranks the list of candidates in order of preference. So, for example, the voter gives a '1' to their first preference, a '2' to their second preference, and so on. In this respect a Borda count election is the same as elections under other preferential voting systems, such as instant-runoff voting, the Single Transferable Vote or Condorcet's method.

The number of points given to candidates for each ranking is determined by the number of candidates standing in the election. Thus, under the simplest form of the Borda count, if there are six candidates in an election then a candidate will receive six points each time they are ranked first, five for being ranked second, and so on, with a candidate receiving 1 point for being ranked last. In other words, where there are n candidates a candidate will receive n points for a first preference, n-1 points for a second preference, n-2 for a third, and so on.

Ranking Candidate Formula Points
1st Andrew (n) 5
2nd Brian (n-1) 4
3rd Catherine (n-2) 3
4th David (n-3) 2
5th Eimear (n-4) 1

Alternatively votes can be counted by giving each candidate a number points equal to the number of candidates ranked lower than them, so that a candidate receives n-1 points for a first preference, n-2 for a second, and so on, with zero points for being ranked last. Another way to express this is that a candidate ranked in ith place receives n-i points. For example, in a five candidate election, the number of points assigned for the preferences expressed by a voter on a single ballot paper might be:

Ranking Candidate Formula Points
1st Andrew (n-1) 4
2nd Brian (n-2) 3
3rd Catherine (n-3) 2
4th David (n-4) 1
5th Eimear (n-5) 0

When all votes have been counted, and the points added up, the candidate with most points wins. We have already noted that the Borda count is a preferential voting system. Because, from each voter, candidates receive a certain number of points, the Borda count is also classified as a positional voting system. Other positional methods include the 'first-past-the-post' (plurality) system, approval voting and the limited vote.

An example

Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

  • Memphis, the largest city, but far from the others (42% of voters)
  • Nashville, near the center of the state (26% of voters)
  • Chattanooga, somewhat east (15% of voters)
  • Knoxville, far to the northeast (17% of voters)

The preferences of each region's voters are:

42% of voters
Far-West
26% of voters
Center
15% of voters
Center-East
17% of voters
Far-East
  1. Memphis
  2. Nashville
  3. Chattanooga
  4. Knoxville
  1. Nashville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Knoxville
  4. Memphis
  1. Chattanooga
  2. Knoxville
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis
  1. Knoxville
  2. Chattanooga
  3. Nashville
  4. Memphis


If the various rankings given to each candidate are added up they are as follows.

City First Second Third Fourth
Memphis 42% 0% 0% 58%
Nashville 26% 42% 32% 0%
Chattanooga 15% 43% 42% 0%
Knoxville 17% 15% 26% 42%

It can be seen above, for example, that Chattanooga is ranked first by 15% of voters, second by 43%, third by 42%, and last by no voters at all. To give points to each candidate for these rankings this example will use the formula, explained above, whereby a candidate receives one point for each time a candidate is ranked lower than them (or n-i points). Thus when Chattanooga's votes are added up the results are calculated as: (15*3)+(43*2)+(42*1)+(0*0) = 173. When the points of all candidates are added up the results are as follows:

City First Second Third Fourth Total points
Memphis 42*3 0 0 58*0 126
Nashville 26*3 42*2 32*1 0 194
Chattanooga 15*3 43*2 42*1 0 173
Knoxville 17*3 15*2 26*1 42*0 107

Result: The winner of the election is Nashville as it has 194 points, which is more than any other candidate.

Variants

As noted above, there is more than one formula for assigning points for each ranking of a candidate. In Nauru a distinctive formula is used based on increasingly small fractions of points. Under the system a candidate receives 1 point for a first preference, ½ a point for a second preference, ⅓ for third preference, and so on. This method is far more favourable to candidates with many first preferences than the conventional Borda count. In Kiribati a variant is used which uses a traditional Borda formula, but in which voters only rank four candidates, irrespective of how many are standing.[1]

Truncated ballots

A further way in which versions of the Borda count differ is the method for dealing with truncated ballots, that is, ballots on which a voter has not expressed a full list of preferences. There are several methods:

  • The simplest method is to allow candidates to rank as many or as few candidates as they wish, but simply give every unranked candidate the minimum number of points. For example, if there are 10 candidates, and a voter votes for candidate A first and candidate B second, leaving everyone else unranked, candidate A receives 9 or 10 points (depending on the formula used), candidate B receives 8 or 9 points, and all other candidates receive either zero or 1. However this method allows strategic voting in the form of bullet voting; that is, voting only for one candidate and leaving every other candidate unranked. This variant makes a bullet vote more effective than a fully-ranked ballot.
  • Under a system known as the 'modified Borda count', the number of points given for a voter's first and subsequent preferences is determined by the total number of candidates they have actually ranked, rather than the total number standing. This means, in other words, that if there are ten candidates but a voter ranks only five then their first preference will receive only four (k-1) or five (k) points, depending on the formula used (k being equal to the number of candidates ranked); their second preference will receive 3 or 4 points, their next 2 or 3, and so on. This method effectively penalises voters who do not rank a full ballot, by diminishing the number of points their vote distributes among candidates.
  • Voters can simply be obliged to rank all candidates. This is the method used in Nauru.
  • Voters can be permitted to rank only a subset of the total number of candidates, but obliged to rank all of these, with all unranked candidates being given zero points. This is the system used in Kiribati.

Multiple winners

The system invented by Jean-Charles de Borda was intended for use in elections with a single winner, but it is also possible to conduct a Borda count with more than one winner, by electing those candidates with the most points. In other words, if there are two seats to be filled then the two candidates with most points win, in a three seat election the three candidates with most points, and so on. In Nauru, which uses the multi-seat variant of the Borda count, parliamentary constituencies of two and four seats are used.

Other systems

A number of voting systems other than the Borda count employ its system of assigning points for rankings. The Quota Borda System is a system of proportional representation in multi-seat constituencies that uses the Borda count. The Nanson and Baldwin methods are single winner voting systems that combine elements of the Borda count and instant run-off voting. Unlike the Borda count, Nanson and Baldwin are majoritarian and Condorcet methods.

As a consensual method

Unlike most other voting systems, in the Borda count it is possible for a candidate who is the first preference of an absolute majority of voters to fail to be elected. This is because the Borda count affords greater importance to a voter's lower preferences than most other systems, including other preferential methods such as instant-runoff voting and Condorcet's method. The Borda count tends to favour candidates supported by a broad consensus among voters, rather than the candidate who is necessarily the favourite of a majority. For this reason some of its supporters see it as a method that promotes consensus and avoids the 'tyranny of the majority'. Advocates argue, for example, that where the majority candidate is strongly opposed by a large minority of the electorate, the Borda winner may have higher overall utility than the majority winner. On grounds such as these, the de Borda Institute of Northern Ireland advocates the use of a form of referendum based on the Borda count in divided societies such as Northern Ireland, the Balkans and Kashmir.

Because it will not necessarily elect a candidate who is the first preference of a majority of voters, the Borda count is said by scholars to fail the majority criterion. It is also theoretically possible for such a candidate to fail to be elected under approval voting.

An example

Imagine an election in which 100 voters express the following preferences:

# 51 voters 5 voters 23 voters 21 voters
1st Andrew Catherine Brian David
2nd Catherine Brian Catherine Catherine
3rd Brian David David Brian
4th David Andrew Andrew Andrew

The Borda scores of the candidates are:

  • Andrew: 153
  • Catherine: 205
  • Brian: 151
  • David: 91

Under most single winner voting systems – including 'first-past-the-post' (plurality), instant-runoff and Condorcet's method – Andrew would have been the winning candidate. However under the Borda count Catherine has the highest Borda score and so is elected instead. Favouring Andrew as the winner is the fact that he is supported by an unambiguous absolute majority of voters. On the other hand he is the last preference of almost 49 voters, which suggests that he may be strongly opposed by almost one half of the electorate. Catherine, on the other hand, while she receives only a handful of first preference votes, is at least the second choice of all voters. This seems to suggest that she is broadly acceptable to all voters.

Potential for tactical manipulation

Tactical voting

Like most voting systems, the Borda count is vulnerable to tactical voting. In particular, it is vulnerable to the tactics of 'compromising'–that is, voters can help avoid the election of a less preferred candidate by insincerely raising the position of a more preferred candidate on their ballot–and 'burying'–where voters can help a more preferred candidate by insincerely lowering the position of a less preferred candidate on their ballot.

An effective tactic is to combine these two strategies. For example, if there are two candidates whom a voter considers to be the most likely to win, the voter can maximise his impact on the contest between these front runners by ranking the candidate whom he likes more in first place, and ranking the candidate whom he likes less in last place. If neither front runner is his sincere first or last choice, the voter is employing both the compromising and burying tactics at once. If many voters employ such strategies, then the result will no longer reflect the sincere preferences of the electorate.

Using the above example based on choosing the capital of Tennessee, if polls suggest a toss-up between Nashville and Chattanooga, citizens of Knoxville might change their ranking to

  1. Chattanooga (compromising their sincere first choice, Knoxville)
  2. Knoxville
  3. Memphis (burying their sincere third choice, Nashville)
  4. Nashville

If many Knoxville voters voted in this way it would result in the election of Chattanooga. Citizens of Chattanooga could also increase the likelihood of the election of their city by voting tactically, but would require the assistance of some tactical voters from Knoxville to be successful.

In response to the issue of strategic manipulation in the Borda count, M. de Borda said "My scheme is only intended for honest men". The academic Donald G. Saari has created a mathematical framework for evaluating positional methods in which he claims to show that the Borda count has fewer opportunities for tactical voting than other positional methods, such as plurality voting.

Strategic nomination

The Borda count is highly vulnerable to a form of strategic nomination called 'teaming' or 'cloning'. This means that when more candidates run with similar ideologies, the probability of one of those candidates winning increases. Therefore, under the Borda count, it is to a faction's advantage to run as many candidates in that faction as they can. For example, even in a single seat election, it would be to the advantage of a political party to stand as many candidates as possible in an election. In this respect the Borda count differs from many other single winner systems, such as the 'first past the post' plurality system, in which a political faction is disadvantaged by running too many candidates. Under systems such as plurality 'splitting' a party's vote in this way can lead to the spoiler effect, which harms the chances of any of a faction's candidates being elected.

In 1980, William Gehrlein and Peter Fishburn compared the Borda count to other positional methods, such as plurality and approval voting. They investigated the likelihood of a positional method choosing the same candidate when one modified the set of candidates by eliminating one losing candidate from a three candidate election and two losing candidates from a four candidate election. They found that the Borda count was the positional rule which maximises the probability of electing the same candidate after this modification of the choice set.

Evaluation by criteria

Scholars of electoral systems often compare them using mathematically defined voting system criteria. From among these, the Borda count satisfies the monotonicity criterion, the consistency criterion, the participation criterion, the plurality criterion (trivially), reversal symmetry, and the Condorcet loser criterion. It does not satisfy the Condorcet criterion, the independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion, the independence of clones criterion, the later-no-harm criterion or the majority criterion.

The variant of the Borda count that permits bullet voting satisfies the plurality criterion, but the 'modified Borda count' does not. Variants that oblige voters to rank, and only rank, a certain specified number of candidates satisfy the same criteria as the conventional Borda count.

Current uses

Political uses

The Borda count is used for certain political elections in at least three countries, Slovenia and the tiny Micronesian nations of Kiribati and Nauru. In Slovenia the Borda count is used to elect two of the ninety members of the National Assembly. One member represents a constituency of ethnic Italians, the other a constituency of the Hungarian minority. As noted above, members of the Parliament of Nauru are elected based on a variant of the Borda count that involves two departures from the normal practice: (1) multi-seat constituencies, of either two or four seats, and (2) a point allocation formula that involves increasingly small fractions of points for each ranking, rather than whole points. In Kiribati the president (or Beretitenti) is elected by the plurality system, but a variant of the Borda count is used to select either three or four candidates to stand in the election. The constituency consists of members of the legislature (Maneaba). Voters in the legislature rank only four candidates, with all other candidates receiving zero points. Since at least 1991 tactical voting has been an important feature of the nominating process.

The Borda count has been used for non-governmental purposes at certain peace conferences in Northern Ireland, where it has been used to help achieve consensus between participants including members of Sinn Féin, the Ulster Unionists, and the political wing of the UDA.

Other uses

The Borda count, and points based systems similar to it, are often used to determine awards in competitions. The Borda count is a popular method for granting awards for sports in the United States, and is used in determining the Most Valuable Player in Major League Baseball, by the Associated Press and United Press International to rank players in NCAA sports, and other contests. The Eurovision Song Contest also uses a positional voting method similar to the Borda count, with a different distribution of points. The Borda count is used for wine trophy judging by the Australian Society of Viticulture and Oenology, and by the RoboCup autonomous robot soccer competition at the Center for Computing Technologies, in the University of Bremen in Germany. The People's Remix Competition uses a Borda variant where the voter ranks only the top three contestants.

The Borda count is used in a number of educational institutions in the United States, such as at the University of Michigan College of Literature, Science and the Arts to elect the Student Government, to elect the Michigan Student Assembly for the university at large, at the University of Missouri Graduate-Professional Council to elect its officers, at the University of California Los Angeles Graduate Student Association to elect its officers, in the Civil Liberties Union of Harvard University to elect its officers, at Southern Illinois University at Carbondale to elect officers to the Faculty Senate, and at Arizona State University to elect officers to the Department of Mathematics and Statistics assembly. It is also used to elect faculty members to committees at Wheaton College, Massachusetts. Borda count is used to break ties for member elections of the faculty personnel committee of the School of Business Administration at the College of William and Mary.

In professional societies, the Borda count is used to elect the Board of Governors of the International Society for Cryobiology, the management committee of Tempo sustainable design network, located in Cornwall, United Kingdom, and to elect members to Research Area Committees of the U.S. Wheat and Barley Scab Initiative. The Borda count is one of the feature selection methods used by the OpenGL Architecture Review Board.

History

A form of the Borda count was one of the voting methods employed in the Roman Senate beginning around the year 105. The system is thought have been discovered independently by at least two men: Nicholas of Cusa, who in 1433 unsuccessfully suggested the method as a way of electing the Holy Roman Emperor, and Jean-Charles de Borda, who devised the system in June of 1770. Borda invented his system as a fair way to elect members to the French Academy of Sciences, and first published his method in 1781 as Mémoire sur les élections au scrutin in the Histoire de l'Académie Royale des Sciences, Paris. The method was used by the Academy from 1784 until being quashed by Napoleon in 1800.

The Republic of Nauru became independent from Australia in 1968. Before independence, and for three years afterwards, Nauru used instant-runoff voting, importing the system from Australia, but since 1971 a variant of the Borda count has been used.

References

  1. ^ Reilly, Benjamin. "Social Choice in the South Seas: Electoral Innovation and the Borda Count in the Pacific Island Countries" (PDF).

See also

Further reading

  • Chaotic Elections!, by Donald G. Saari (ISBN 0-8218-2847-9), is a book that describes various voting systems using a mathematical model, and supports the use of the Borda count.