Jump to content

Daniel Kahneman: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Mc8708 (talk | contribs)
Mc8708 (talk | contribs)
Undid revision 1213432707 by Isaidnoway (talk) The sentences on how authorship was determined by Kahneman and Tversky comes directly from Dr. Kahneman. I am a research assistant and I am currently helping with editing his wikipedia page and he requested that I add in those lines. Thank you!
Line 82: Line 82:


===Judgment and decision-making===
===Judgment and decision-making===
This period marks the beginning of Kahneman's lengthy collaboration with [[Amos Tversky]]. Together, Kahneman and Tversky published a series of seminal articles in the general field of judgment and decision-making, culminating in the publication of their [[prospect theory]] in 1979 (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Following this, the pair teamed with [[Paul Slovic]] to edit a compilation entitled "Judgement Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (1982) that proved to be an important summary of their work and of other recent advances that had influenced their thinking. Kahneman was ultimately awarded the [[Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] in 2002 for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty.
This period marks the beginning of Kahneman's lengthy collaboration with [[Amos Tversky]]. Together, Kahneman and Tversky published a series of seminal articles in the general field of judgment and decision-making, culminating in the publication of their [[prospect theory]] in 1979 (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Following this, the pair teamed with [[Paul Slovic]] to edit a compilation entitled "Judgement Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (1982) that proved to be an important summary of their work and of other recent advances that had influenced their thinking. Kahneman was ultimately awarded the [[Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics]] in 2002 for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty.

Kahneman and Tversky published seven articles in peer-reviewed journals in the years 1971–1979.  They tossed a coin for authorship in their first article and alternated authorship in subsequent publications until 1980, but neglected to indicate that authorship was random.


In his Nobel biography Kahneman states that his collaboration with Tversky began after Kahneman had invited Tversky to give a guest lecture to one of Kahneman's seminars at Hebrew University in 1968 or 1969.<ref name="NobelPrize Bio 2002"/> Their first jointly written paper, "Belief in the Law of Small Numbers," was published in 1971 (Tversky & Kahneman, 1971). They published seven articles in peer-reviewed journals in the years 1971–1979. Aside from "Prospect Theory," the most important of these articles was "Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (Tversky & Kahneman, 1974), which was published in the prestigious journal ''[[Science (journal)|Science]]'' and introduced the notion of [[anchoring (cognitive bias)|anchoring]]. Kahneman and Tversky spent an entire year at an office in the Van Leer Institute in Jerusalem. They spent more than three years revising an early version of prospect theory that was completed in early 1975. The final version was published in 1979.<ref name=":0" />
In his Nobel biography Kahneman states that his collaboration with Tversky began after Kahneman had invited Tversky to give a guest lecture to one of Kahneman's seminars at Hebrew University in 1968 or 1969.<ref name="NobelPrize Bio 2002"/> Their first jointly written paper, "Belief in the Law of Small Numbers," was published in 1971 (Tversky & Kahneman, 1971). They published seven articles in peer-reviewed journals in the years 1971–1979. Aside from "Prospect Theory," the most important of these articles was "Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (Tversky & Kahneman, 1974), which was published in the prestigious journal ''[[Science (journal)|Science]]'' and introduced the notion of [[anchoring (cognitive bias)|anchoring]]. Kahneman and Tversky spent an entire year at an office in the Van Leer Institute in Jerusalem. They spent more than three years revising an early version of prospect theory that was completed in early 1975. The final version was published in 1979.<ref name=":0" />

Revision as of 20:38, 13 March 2024

Daniel Kahneman
Kahneman in 2009
Born (1934-03-05) March 5, 1934 (age 90)[1]
NationalityAmerican, Israeli
EducationHebrew University (BA)
University of California, Berkeley (MA, PhD)
Known for
Spouses
PartnerBarbara Tversky
Awards
Scientific career
Fields
Institutions
ThesisAn analytical model of the semantic differential (1961)
Doctoral advisorSusan M. Ervin-Tripp
Notable students
Websitescholar.princeton.edu/kahneman/

Daniel Kahneman (/ˈkɑːnəmən/; Hebrew: דניאל כהנמן; born March 5, 1934) is an Israeli-American author, psychologist and economist notable for his work on hedonic psychology, psychology of judgment and decision-making. He is also known for his work in behavioral economics, for which he was awarded the 2002 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (shared with Vernon L. Smith). His empirical findings challenge the assumption of human rationality prevailing in modern economic theory.

With Amos Tversky and others, Kahneman established a cognitive basis for common human errors that arise from heuristics and biases, and developed prospect theory.

In 2011, he was named by Foreign Policy magazine in its list of top global thinkers.[2] In the same year his book Thinking, Fast and Slow, which summarizes much of his research, was published and became a best seller.[3] In 2015, The Economist listed him as the seventh most influential economist in the world.[4]

He is professor emeritus of psychology and public affairs at Princeton University's Princeton School of Public and International Affairs. Kahneman is a founding partner of TGG Group, a business and philanthropy consulting company. He was married to cognitive psychologist and Royal Society Fellow Anne Treisman, who died in 2018.[5]

Early life

Daniel Kahneman was born in Tel Aviv, Mandatory Palestine, in 1934, where his mother, Rachel, was visiting relatives. His parents were Lithuanian Jews who had emigrated to France in the early 1920s. He spent his childhood years in Paris. Kahneman and his family were in Paris when it was occupied by Nazi Germany in 1940. His father, Efrayim, was picked up in the first major round-up of French Jews, but he was released after six weeks due to the intervention of his employer, La Cagoule backer Eugène Schueller.[6]: 52  The family was on the run for the remainder of the war, and survived, except for the death of Kahneman's father due to diabetes in 1944. Kahneman and his family then moved to British Mandatory Palestine in 1948, just before the creation of the state of Israel.[5]

Kahneman has written of his experience in Nazi-occupied France, explaining in part why he entered the field of psychology:

It must have been late 1941 or early 1942. Jews were required to wear the Star of David and to obey a 6 p.m. curfew. I had gone to play with a Christian friend and had stayed too late. I turned my brown sweater inside out to walk the few blocks home. As I was walking down an empty street, I saw a German soldier approaching. He was wearing the black uniform that I had been told to fear more than others – the one worn by specially recruited SS soldiers. As I came closer to him, trying to walk fast, I noticed that he was looking at me intently. Then he beckoned me over, picked me up, and hugged me. I was terrified that he would notice the star inside my sweater. He was speaking to me with great emotion, in German. When he put me down, he opened his wallet, showed me a picture of a boy, and gave me some money. I went home more certain than ever that my mother was right: people were endlessly complicated and interesting.

— [5]

Education and early career

In 1954 Kahneman received his Bachelor of Science degree, with a major in psychology and a minor in mathematics, from the Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Israeli intellectual Yeshayahu Leibowitz, whom Kahneman describes as influential in his intellectual development, was Kahneman's chemistry teacher at Beit-Hakerem High School, and Kahneman's physiology professor at university.[7] Kahneman was average in mathematics, but he thrived in psychology.[8] Kahneman was led to psychology when he discovered in his teens that he was more interested in why people believe in God than in whether God exists, and more interested in indignation than in ethics.[8]

In 1954 he began his military service as a second lieutenant, serving for a year in infantry.[8] He then served in the psychology department of the Israeli Defense Forces. He developed a structured interview for combat recruits, which remained in use in the IDF for several decades. Kahneman describes his military service as a "very important period" in his life.[7][9]

In 1958 he went to the United States to study for his PhD in Psychology at the University of California, Berkeley. His 1961 dissertation, advised by Susan Ervin, examined relations between adjectives in the semantic differential and allowed him to "engage in two of [his] favorite pursuits: the analysis of complex correlational structures and FORTRAN programming."[5]

Academic career

Cognitive psychology

Kahneman began his academic career as a lecturer in psychology at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem in 1961.[5] He was promoted to senior lecturer in 1966. His early work focused on visual perception and attention. For example, his first publication in the prestigious journal Science was entitled "Pupil Diameter and Load on Memory" (Kahneman & Beatty, 1966).[10] During this period, Kahneman was a visiting scientist at the University of Michigan (1965–66) and the Applied Psychology Research Unit in Cambridge (1968/1969, summers). He was a fellow at the Center for Cognitive Studies, and a lecturer in cognitive psychology at Harvard University in 1966/1967. His work on attention led to a book, Attention and Effort, in which he presented a theory of effort based on studies of pupillary changes during mental tasks.[11] Much later Kahneman developed rules of counterfactual thinking, and published "Norm Theory" with Dale Miller.[12]

Judgment and decision-making

This period marks the beginning of Kahneman's lengthy collaboration with Amos Tversky. Together, Kahneman and Tversky published a series of seminal articles in the general field of judgment and decision-making, culminating in the publication of their prospect theory in 1979 (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Following this, the pair teamed with Paul Slovic to edit a compilation entitled "Judgement Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (1982) that proved to be an important summary of their work and of other recent advances that had influenced their thinking. Kahneman was ultimately awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2002 for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty.

Kahneman and Tversky published seven articles in peer-reviewed journals in the years 1971–1979.  They tossed a coin for authorship in their first article and alternated authorship in subsequent publications until 1980, but neglected to indicate that authorship was random.

In his Nobel biography Kahneman states that his collaboration with Tversky began after Kahneman had invited Tversky to give a guest lecture to one of Kahneman's seminars at Hebrew University in 1968 or 1969.[5] Their first jointly written paper, "Belief in the Law of Small Numbers," was published in 1971 (Tversky & Kahneman, 1971). They published seven articles in peer-reviewed journals in the years 1971–1979. Aside from "Prospect Theory," the most important of these articles was "Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases" (Tversky & Kahneman, 1974), which was published in the prestigious journal Science and introduced the notion of anchoring. Kahneman and Tversky spent an entire year at an office in the Van Leer Institute in Jerusalem. They spent more than three years revising an early version of prospect theory that was completed in early 1975. The final version was published in 1979.[7]

Kahneman left Hebrew University in 1978 to take a position at the University of British Columbia.[5]

In 2021, Kahneman and co-authors Olivier Sibony and Cass Sunstein contributed to the field with work on unwanted variability in human judgments of the same problem, which they term 'noise'. In Noise: A Flaw in Human Judgment, they write that due to factors such as cognitive biases, group dynamics, mood, stress, fatigue, and differences in skill between assessors/decision makers/judges, judgements that should ideally be identical in fact often differ a lot. This gives rise to injustices, hazards and costs of various types. Furthermore, it does so in a way that is distinct from statistical bias and which is affected by cognitive biases but not limited to their influence. In the book, which received much press, they explain what noise is, how it can be detected and how it can be reduced – which can also reduce bias.

Behavioral economics

Kahneman and Tversky were both fellows at the Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences at Stanford University in the academic year 1977–1978. A young economist named Richard Thaler was a visiting professor at the Stanford branch of the National Bureau of Economic Research during that same year. According to Kahneman, "[Thaler and I] soon became friends, and have ever since had a considerable influence on each other's thinking."[5] Building in part on prospect theory and Kahneman and Tversky's body of work, Thaler published "Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice" in 1980, a paper which Kahneman has called "the founding text of behavioral economics."[5] Richard Thaler obtained a grant from the Russell Sage Foundation to spend the academic year 1982-83 with Kahneman at the University of British Columbia.[13]  Together with Kahneman’s friend Jack Knetsch they worked on two papers that later appeared in significant economic journals, on fairness and on the endowment effect.[14]

Kahneman and Tversky moved to different cities, reducing the intensity and exclusivity of their earlier period of joint collaboration.[8] According to Kahneman the collaboration 'tapered off' in the early 1980s, although they tried to revive it.[15] Factors included Tversky receiving most of the external credit for the output of the partnership, and a reduction in the generosity with which Tversky and Kahneman interacted with each other.[16] They would continue to publish together until the end of Tversky's life, but the period when Kahneman published almost exclusively with Tversky ended in 1983, when he published two papers with Anne Treisman, his wife since 1978.

After publishing multiple articles and chapters in all but one of the years spanning the period 1979–1986 (for a total of 23 published works in 8 years),[17] Kahneman published exactly one chapter during the years 1987–1989.[17][18] A few papers on decision making appeared after that hiatus, notably cumulative prospect theory (Tversky and Kahneman, 1992) and an explanation of risk-taking by unrealistic “bold forecasts” (Kahneman and Lovallo, 1993), but the focus of Kahneman’s research from that time was the study of subjective experience.[19][20]

Variants of Utility

Kahneman elaborated a distinction between two notions of utility.  Experienced utility is the subjective concept that Jeremy Bentham had in mind in his discussion of pleasure and pain.  Decision utility is the more modern usage in economics and decision theory, where utility explains choices and is derived from choices.[21][22] The experienced utility of an episode was formalized as the temporal integration of momentary utility.[22]

The analysis of experienced utility led to the concepts of remembered and predicted utility. Predicted utility (better known as affective forecasting)[23] is the conscious expectation of the experienced utility of an event or episode.[24] Remembered utility is the retrospective evaluation of a past experience.[22][21]. The essential finding of many experiments is that predictions and memories of affective experiences are systematically inaccurate.  Furthermore, the remembered evaluation of past episodes (remembered utility) is the best predictor of subsequent decision utility.[25][26][22][27]

One of the cognitive biases of remembered utility is called the peak–end rule. It affects how people remember the pleasantness or unpleasantness of experiences. It states that a persons overall impression of past events is determined, for the most part, not by the total pleasure and suffering it contained, but by how it felt at its peak and at its end.[28] For example, the memory of a painful colonoscopy is improved if the examination is extended by three minutes in which the scope is still inside but not moved anymore, resulting in a moderately uncomfortable sensation. This extended colonoscopy, despite involving more pain overall, is remembered less negatively due to the reduced pain at the end. This even increases the likelihood for the patient to return for subsequent procedures.[29]

Kahneman explains this distortion in terms of the difference between two selves: the experiencing self, which is aware of pleasure and pain as they are happening, and the remembering self, which shows the aggregate pleasure and pain over an extended period of time. The distortions due to the peak–end rule happen on the level of the remembering self.[21][30][31][32]

Happiness and life satisfaction

The analysis of the experienced utility of short episodes readily extends to the broader notion of happiness. This connection led Kahneman, together with Ed Diener and Norbert Schwarz to organize a workshop, which yielded a book that covered a range of topics in hedonic psychology, which they defined as “…the study of what makes experiences and life pleasant or unpleasant.[33] It is concerned with feelings of pleasure and pain, of interest and boredom, of joy and sorrow, and of satisfaction and dissatisfaction. It is also concerned with the whole range of circumstances, from the biological to the societal, that occasion suffering and enjoyment.[33]

Most studies of well-being use retrospective questions such as “How happy are you these days?”. A smaller number of studies use experience sampling, in which people are probed at random times during the day, and asked to rate their experience of the present moment.  Much later (source TED talk) Kahneman described this distinction in terms of two selves: the experiencing self, which is aware of pleasure and pain as they are happening, and the remembering self, which shows the aggregate pleasure and pain over an extended period of time.[34]   

Kahneman initially believed that the happiness of the experiencing self is the true measure of well-being.  Around 2000, he assembled a “Dream team”, which included a notable economist, the late Alan Krueger, and three psychologists, David Schkade, Norbert Schwarz and Arthur Stone.  The ambitious mission of the team was to create a measure of experienced happiness that economists could take seriously.  As a more practical substitute to the experience sampling techniques of the time, the team developed The Day-Reconstruction Method, in which participants described the day as a sequence of episodes, and rated the experience on several affective dimensions.[35][36] Kahneman also participated in the formulation of the well-being module of the Gallup World Poll.[37]  The effort to measure experienced happiness was only partly successful. Measures of affect are routinely included in well-being questionnaires, but the idea that experienced happiness is the better concept did not hold. Kahneman has defined happiness in terms of "what I experience here and now",[38] but says that in reality humans pursue life satisfaction,[39] which "is connected to a large degree to social yardsticks–achieving goals, meeting expectations."[40][41][42]

Focusing illusion

With David Schkade, Kahneman developed the notion of the focusing illusion to explain in part the mistakes people make when estimating the effects of different scenarios on their future happiness (also known as affective forecasting, which has been studied extensively by Daniel Gilbert).[43][35] The "illusion" occurs when people consider the impact of one specific factor on their overall happiness, they tend to greatly exaggerate the importance of that factor, while overlooking the numerous other factors that would in most cases have a greater impact.

A good example is provided by Kahneman and Schkade's 1998 paper, "Does living in California make people happy? A focusing illusion in judgments of life satisfaction".[43] In that paper, students in the Midwest and in California reported similar levels of life satisfaction, but the Midwesterners thought their Californian peers would be happier. The only distinguishing information the Midwestern students had when making these judgments was the fact that their hypothetical peers lived in California. Thus, they "focused" on this distinction, thereby overestimating the effect of the weather in California on its residents' satisfaction with life.

Teaching

Kahneman taught at the Hebrew University in Jerusalem from 1970-1978. He then became a professor at the University of British Columbia, ending in 1986. Next, he taught at the University of California, Berkeley, from 1986-1994.[44] Now, Kahneman is a senior scholar and faculty member emeritus at Princeton University's Department of Psychology and Princeton School of Public and International Affairs. He is also a fellow at Hebrew University and a Gallup Senior Scientist.[45]

Personal life

Kahneman's first wife was Irah Kahneman,[46] an Israeli social researcher, with whom he had two children. His son has schizophrenia, and his daughter, Lenore Shoham, works in technology.[47][48]

His second wife was the cognitive psychologist Anne Treisman, from 1978 until her death in 2018. As of 2014, they lived part-time in Berkeley, California.[49][50] As of 2020, he lives in New York City with Barbara Tversky, the widow of his long-time collaborator Amos Tversky.[51][7]

Kahneman's paternal uncle was Rabbi Yosef Shlomo Kahaneman, the head of the Ponevezh Yeshiva.[7]

In 2015 Kahneman described himself as a very hard worker, as "a worrier" and "not a jolly person". But, despite this, he said, "I'm quite capable of great enjoyment, and I've had a great life."[52]

Awards and recognition

Honorary Degrees

Notable contributions

Books

  • Kahneman, Daniel (1973). Attention and Effort. Prentice-Hall.
  • Kahneman, Daniel; Slovic, Paul; Tversky, Amos (1982). Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge University Press.
  • Kahneman, Daniel; Diener, E.; Schwarz, N. (1999). Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology. Russell Sage Foundation.
  • Kahneman, Daniel; Tversky, Amos (2000). Choices, Values and Frames. Cambridge University Press.
  • Kahneman, Daniel; Gilovich, Thomas; Griffin, Dale (2002). Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521792608.
  • Kahneman, Daniel (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. Farrar, Straus and Giroux. ISBN 978-0374275631. (Reviewed by Freeman Dyson in New York Review of Books, 22 December 2011, pp. 40–44.)
  • Kahneman, Daniel; Sibony, Olivier; Sunstein, Cass R. (2021). Noise: A Flaw in Human Judgment. William Collins. ISBN 978-0008308995.

Interviews

  • "Can We Trust Our Intuitions?" in Alex Voorhoeve Conversations on Ethics. Oxford University Press, 2009. ISBN 978-0-19-921537-9 (Discusses Kahneman's views about the reliability of moral intuitions [case judgments] and the relevance of his work for the search for "reflective equilibrium" in moral philosophy.)

Radio interviews

Online interviews

Television interviews

See also

References

  1. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2002". NobelPrize.org.
  2. ^ "The FP Top 100 Global Thinkers. 71 Daniel Kahneman". foreignpolicy.com. November 28, 2011. Retrieved November 3, 2012.
  3. ^ "The New York Times Best Seller List – December 25, 2011" (PDF). www.hawes.com. Retrieved August 17, 2014.
  4. ^ "Influential economists – That ranking". The Economist. January 2, 2015. Retrieved April 4, 2015.
  5. ^ a b c d e f g h i Kahneman, Daniel (2002). "Daniel Kahneman: Biographical". Nobel Committee. Retrieved May 1, 2017.
  6. ^ Lewis, Michael (2017) [1st pub. in the US by W.W. Norton & Company, Inc, 2016]. The Undoing Project: A Friendship That Changed Our Minds. New York: Penguin Random House. ISBN 978-0-14-198304-2.
  7. ^ a b c d e "Interview with Daniel Kahneman". Interviews with Max Raskin. Retrieved March 1, 2022.
  8. ^ a b c d "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2002". NobelPrize.org. Retrieved November 20, 2023.
  9. ^ Akst, Daniel. "Daniel Kahneman: How Companies Can Improve Their Hiring Process". WSJ. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  10. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Beatty, Jackson (1966). "Pupil Diameter and Load on Memory". Science. 154 (3756): 1583–1585. ISSN 0036-8075.
  11. ^ Kahneman, Daniel (1973). Attention and effort. Prentice-Hall series in experimental psychology. Englewood Cliffs, N.J: Prentice-Hall. ISBN 978-0-13-050518-7.
  12. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Miller, Dale T. (April 1986). "Norm theory: Comparing reality to its alternatives". The Psychological Review. 93 (2): 136–153. doi:10.1037/0033-295X.93.2.136. ISSN 1939-1471.
  13. ^ "Daniel Kahneman and Richard Thaler on the Beginning of Behavioral Economics | RSF". www.russellsage.org. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  14. ^ "In Remembrance". www.benefitcostanalysis.org. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  15. ^ "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2002".
  16. ^ Michael Lewis. "The Undoing Project: A Friendship that Changed the World". Penguin, 2016 (ISBN 9780141983035)
  17. ^ a b "Publications". Daniel Kahneman. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  18. ^ Kahneman, Daniel (1988). Tietz, Reinhard; Albers, Wulf; Selten, Reinhard (eds.). "Experimental Economics: A Psychological Perspective". Bounded Rational Behavior in Experimental Games and Markets. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer: 11–18. doi:10.1007/978-3-642-48356-1_2. ISBN 978-3-642-48356-1.
  19. ^ Tversky, Amos; Kahneman, Daniel (October 1, 1992). "Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty". Journal of Risk and Uncertainty. 5 (4): 297–323. doi:10.1007/BF00122574. ISSN 1573-0476.
  20. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Lovallo, Dan (1993). "Timid Choices and Bold Forecasts: A Cognitive Perspective on Risk Taking". Management Science. 39 (1): 17–31. ISSN 0025-1909.
  21. ^ a b c Kahneman, Daniel (2011). "35. Two Selves". Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.
  22. ^ a b c d Kahneman, D.; Wakker, P. P.; Sarin, R. (May 1, 1997). "Back to Bentham? Explorations of Experienced Utility". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112 (2): 375–406. doi:10.1162/003355397555235. ISSN 0033-5533.
  23. ^ Wilson, Timothy D; Gilbert, Daniel T (2003), "Affective Forecasting", Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, Elsevier, pp. 345–411, doi:10.1016/s0065-2601(03)01006-2, retrieved March 13, 2024
  24. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Snell, Jackie (July 1992). "Predicting a changing taste: Do people know what they will like?". Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. 5 (3): 187–200. doi:10.1002/bdm.3960050304. ISSN 0894-3257.
  25. ^ Fredrickson, Barbara L.; Kahneman, Daniel (1993). "Duration neglect in retrospective evaluations of affective episodes". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 65 (1): 45–55. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.65.1.45. ISSN 1939-1315.
  26. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Fredrickson, Barbara L.; Schreiber, Charles A.; Redelmeier, Donald A. (November 1993). "When More Pain Is Preferred to Less: Adding a Better End". Psychological Science. 4 (6): 401–405. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.1993.tb00589.x. ISSN 0956-7976.
  27. ^ Redelmeier, Donald A; Kahneman, Daniel (July 1996). "Patients' memories of painful medical treatments: real-time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures". Pain. 66 (1): 3–8. doi:10.1016/0304-3959(96)02994-6. ISSN 0304-3959.
  28. ^ Do, Amy M.; Rupert, Alexander V.; Wolford, George (February 1, 2008). "Evaluations of pleasurable experiences: The peak–end rule". Psychonomic Bulletin & Review. 15 (1): 96–98. doi:10.3758/PBR.15.1.96. ISSN 1531-5320. PMID 18605486.
  29. ^ Redelmeier, Donald A.; Katz, Joel; Kahneman, Daniel (July 2003). "Memories of colonoscopy: a randomized trial". Pain. 104 (1–2): 187–194. doi:10.1016/s0304-3959(03)00003-4. hdl:10315/7959. ISSN 0304-3959. PMID 12855328. S2CID 206055276.
  30. ^ Lazari-Radek, Katarzyna de; Singer, Peter (2014). The Point of View of the Universe: Sidgwick and Contemporary Ethics. Oxford University Press. p. 276.
  31. ^ Chernoff, Naina N. (May 6, 2002). "Memory Vs. Experience: Happiness is Relative". Aps Observer. 15 (5).
  32. ^ Lex Fridman Podcast #65 – Daniel Kahneman: Thinking Fast and Slow, Deep Learning, and AI (2020) [1]
  33. ^ a b Kahneman, Daniel; Diener, Ed; Schwarz, Norbert, eds. (1999). Well-being: the foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. ISBN 978-0-87154-424-7.
  34. ^ Kahneman, Daniel (March 1, 2010), The riddle of experience vs. memory, retrieved March 13, 2024
  35. ^ a b Stone, Arthur A.; Schwartz, Joseph E.; Schkade, David; Schwarz, Norbert; Krueger, Alan; Kahneman, Daniel (2006). "A population approach to the study of emotion: Diurnal rhythms of a working day examined with the day reconstruction method". Emotion. 6 (1): 139–149. doi:10.1037/1528-3542.6.1.139. ISSN 1931-1516.
  36. ^ Kahneman, Daniel; Krueger, Alan B (February 1, 2006). "Developments in the Measurement of Subjective Well-Being". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 20 (1): 3–24. doi:10.1257/089533006776526030. ISSN 0895-3309.
  37. ^ "Are You Happy Now?". Gallup.com. February 10, 2005. Retrieved March 13, 2024.
  38. ^ "Why Nobel Prize Winner Daniel Kahneman Gave Up on Happiness". Haaretz. Retrieved January 20, 2023.
  39. ^ Daniel Kahneman on wellbeing and how to measure it | University of Oxford 2022, retrieved November 16, 2022
  40. ^ Mandel, Amir (October 7, 2018). "Why Nobel Prize Winner Daniel Kahneman Gave Up on Happiness". Haaretz.
  41. ^ Livni, Ephrat (December 21, 2018). "A Nobel Prize-winning psychologist says most people don't really want to be happy". Quartz.
  42. ^ "Daniel Kahneman: Putting Your Intuition on Ice".
  43. ^ a b Schkade, David A.; Kahneman, Daniel (May 6, 2016). "Does Living in California Make People Happy? A Focusing Illusion in Judgments of Life Satisfaction" (PDF). Psychological Science. 9 (5): 340–346. doi:10.1111/1467-9280.00066. ISSN 1467-9280. S2CID 14091201.
  44. ^ "Daniel Kahneman". kahneman.scholar.princeton.edu. Retrieved November 20, 2023.
  45. ^ "Daniel Kahneman, Ph.D." The Gallup Organization. 2012. Archived from the original on November 3, 2012. Retrieved November 3, 2012.
  46. ^ "Daniel Kahneman Facts". In January of 1958, my wife, Irah, and I landed at the San Francisco airport, where the now famous sociologist Amitai Etzioni was waiting to take us to Berkeley, to the Flamingo Motel on University Avenue, and to the beginning of our graduate careers.
  47. ^ "Daniel Kahneman: 'What would I eliminate if I had a magic wand? Overconfidence'". TheGuardian.com. July 18, 2015.
  48. ^ Kahneman, Daniel (December 8, 2002). "Maps of Bounded Rationality: A Perspective on Intuitive Judgement and Choice" (PDF). nobelprize.org/.
  49. ^ "How do we really make decisions?". Horizon. Series 2013-2014. Episode 9. February 24, 2014. Event occurs at 00:20:13. BBC. BBC Two. Retrieved February 19, 2019. I live in Berkeley during summers and I walk a lot.
  50. ^ Shariatmadari, David (July 15, 2015). "A life in ... Interview Daniel Kahneman: 'What would I eliminate if I had a magic wand? Overconfidence'". The Guardian. He has been married since 1978 to the perceptual psychologist Anne Treisman.
  51. ^ Levitt, Steven D. "Daniel Kahneman on Why Our Judgment is Flawed — and What to Do About It (26:20)". People I (Mostly) Admire. Retrieved May 15, 2021.
  52. ^ "Daniel Kahneman: 'What would I eliminate if I had a magic wand? Overconfidence' | Science and nature books | the Guardian".
  53. ^ "APA Award for Distinguished Scientific Contributions". www.apa.org.
  54. ^ "Distinguished Scientific Contribution". Society for Consumer Psychology. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  55. ^ "Apply for Awards Sponsored by Division 1". apadiv1.org. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  56. ^ "Warren Medal Recipients | The Society of Experimental Psychologists". Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  57. ^ "Daniel Kahneman". www.nasonline.org.
  58. ^ "2003 – Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky – Grawemeyer Awards". July 21, 2003. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  59. ^ "APS Member History". search.amphilsoc.org. Retrieved June 10, 2021.
  60. ^ INFORMS. "Decision Analysis Publication Award". INFORMS. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  61. ^ "IPMU - Information Processing and Management of Uncertainty". ipmu.lip6.fr. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  62. ^ gazetteimport (May 11, 2006). "Schelling and Neustadt winners named". Harvard Gazette. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  63. ^ INFORMS. "Frank P. Ramsey Medal". INFORMS. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  64. ^ Cynkar, Amy (April 4, 2007). "A towering figure". Monitor on Psychology. American Psychological Association. Retrieved November 26, 2008. Daniel Kahneman will receive APA's lifetime contributions award at convention for his work challenging human rationality and decision-making.
  65. ^ "John P. McGovern Award Lecture in the Behavioral Sciences". www.aaas.org/. March 11, 2024. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  66. ^ "Psychology". The British Academy. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  67. ^ "2010 Leontief Prize | Economics in Context Initiative". www.bu.edu. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  68. ^ "American Economic Association". www.aeaweb.org. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  69. ^ "The 50 Most Influential People in Global Finance". Bloomberg L.P. Archived from the original on July 16, 2012. Retrieved November 3, 2012.
  70. ^ "Two Systems in the Mind | American Academy of Arts and Sciences". www.amacad.org. January 1, 2012. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  71. ^ "Alex Shakar, Stephen King win Times Book Prizes". Los Angeles Times. April 20, 2012. Retrieved November 3, 2012.
  72. ^ "Daniel Kahneman's Thinking, Fast and Slow Wins Best Book Award From Academies; Milwaukee Journal Sentinel, Slate Magazine, and WGBH/NOVA Also Take Top Prizes in Awards' 10th Year". www.nationalacademies.org. September 13, 2012. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  73. ^ "His Excellency Dr. Daniel Kahneman". www.racef.es. June 14, 2012. Retrieved November 2, 2012.
  74. ^ "Extract from Annual Report—2013". www.cosmosclubfoundation.org. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  75. ^ "2013 SAGE-CASBS Award winner Daniel Kahneman on 'Thinking, Fast and Slow' | Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences". casbs.stanford.edu. October 22, 2013. Retrieved March 11, 2024.
  76. ^ "President Obama Names Presidential Medal of Freedom Recipients". Office of the Press Secretary, The White House. August 8, 2013. Retrieved August 8, 2013.
  77. ^ "Gold Medal Honorees". The National Institute of Social Sciences. Archived from the original on July 2, 2019. Retrieved July 2, 2019.
  78. ^ "Golden Plate Awardees of the American Academy of Achievement". www.achievement.org. American Academy of Achievement.
  79. ^ "2019 Summit Highlights Photo: Anthony D. Romero, Executive Director of the American Civil Liberties Union, presenting the Golden Plate Award to Dr. Daniel Kahneman, a recipient of the Nobel Prize in Economics, at the 2019 International Achievement Summit". American Academy of Achievement.
  80. ^ "The Helen Dinerman Prize". World Association for Public Opinion Research. Retrieved March 12, 2024.
  81. ^ "Commencement 2001: Sketches of the Honorary Degree Recipients". University of Pennsylvania Almanac.
  82. ^ Zaninotto, Enrico. "Kahneman and Cole honorary doctors in economics". www.unitn.it.
  83. ^ "NEW SCHOOL UNIVERSITY TO HOLD 67th COMMENCEMENT CEREMONY ON WEDNESDAY, MAY 21, 2003 AT 2:30 PM AT THE THEATER AT MADISON SQUARE GARDEN". www.newschool.edu.
  84. ^ "Honorary Doctorates". in.bgu.ac.il.
  85. ^ "History of honorary degrees". www.harvard.edu.
  86. ^ "Honorary Graduates". www.uea.ac.uk.
  87. ^ "Honorary degrees – chronological". archives.library.ubc.ca.
  88. ^ "Honorary degrees and doctorates". en.unimib.it.
  89. ^ "Les DHC". www.pantheonsorbonne.fr.
  90. ^ "Honorary degree recipients named". sites.ualberta.ca.
  91. ^ www.uniroma1.it https://www.uniroma1.it/sites/default/files/field_file_allegati/bilanciosociale2017_0.pdf. {{cite web}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)
  92. ^ "Honorary doctorates". www.eur.nl.
  93. ^ "Honorary degree recipients". governance.georgetown.edu.
  94. ^ "Main Speaker Daniel Kahneman". news.umich.edu.
  95. ^ "CMU To Award Five Honorary Degrees". www.cmu.edu.
  96. ^ "Mount Sinai Honors Innovators in Scientific Research and Health Care Philanthropy at 2013 Commencement". www.mountsinai.org.
  97. ^ "Selected honorands". www.cam.ac.uk.
  98. ^ "Honorary Doctorates". www3.huji.ac.il.
  99. ^ "Yale awards 12 honorary degrees at 2014 graduation". news.yale.edu.
  100. ^ "McGill to award 16 honorary degrees". www.mcgill.ca.
  101. ^ "SU to honour foremost thought leaders". www.sun.ac.za.
  102. ^ "Honorary Degrees". bog.haifa.ac.il.
  103. ^ "NOBEL LAUREATE AND HEC PARIS DOCTOR HONORIS CAUSA KAHNEMAN : "I'M A CHEERFUL PESSIMIST"". www.hec.edu.
  104. ^ "Honorary Degree Recipients". www.yorku.ca.
  105. ^ "Daniel Kahneman | When Noise Destroys Our Best of Choices". Jordan Harbinger. June 8, 2021. Retrieved June 15, 2021.

Cite error: A list-defined reference named "EUR.nl Bio" is not used in the content (see the help page).

Cite error: A list-defined reference named "AMACAD November 2011" is not used in the content (see the help page).

Further reading

Awards
Preceded by Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
2002
Served alongside: Vernon L. Smith
Succeeded by