Emissions trading: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
m →‎Definitions: fixing page range dashes using AWB (7151)
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Redirect|Carbon market|the Philippines tourist attraction|Carbon Market}}
Cap and trade is a hat that you trade.{{Redirect|Carbon market|the Philippines tourist attraction|Carbon Market}}
{{See also|Personal carbon trading|carbon offset}}
{{See also|Personal carbon trading|carbon offset}}
[[Image:Coal power plant Datteln 2 Crop1.png|thumb|300px|A coal power plant in Germany. Due to emissions trading, [[coal]] may become a less competitive fuel than other options.]]
[[Image:Coal power plant Datteln 2 Crop1.png|thumb|300px|A coal power plant in Germany. Due to emissions trading, [[coal]] may become a less competitive fuel than other options.]]

Revision as of 18:03, 20 September 2010

Cap and trade is a hat that you trade.

A coal power plant in Germany. Due to emissions trading, coal may become a less competitive fuel than other options.

Emissions trading (also known as cap and trade) is a market-based approach used to control pollution by providing economic incentives for achieving reductions in the emissions of pollutants.[1]

A central authority (usually a governmental body) sets a limit or cap on the amount of a pollutant that can be emitted. The limit or cap is allocated or sold to firms in the form of emissions permits which represent the right to emit or discharge a specific volume of the specified pollutant. Firms are required to hold a number of permits (or credits) equivalent to their emissions. The total number of permits cannot exceed the cap, limiting total emissions to that level. Firms that need to increase their emission permits must buy permits from those who require fewer permits (Stavins 2001, p 4.).[1] The transfer of permits is referred to as a trade. In effect, the buyer is paying a charge for polluting, while the seller is being rewarded for having reduced emissions. Thus, in theory, those who can reduce emissions most cheaply will do so, achieving the pollution reduction at the lowest cost to society.[2]

There are active trading programs in several air pollutants. For greenhouse gases the largest is the European Union Emission Trading Scheme.[3] In the United States there is a national market to reduce acid rain and several regional markets in nitrogen oxides.[4] Markets for other pollutants tend to be smaller and more localized.

Overview

The overall goal of an emissions trading plan is to minimize the cost of meeting a set emissions target.[5] The cap is an enforceable limit on emissions that is usually lowered over time — aiming towards a national emissions reduction target.[5] In other systems a portion of all traded credits must be retired, causing a net reduction in emissions each time a trade occurs. In many cap-and-trade systems, organizations which do not pollute may also participate, thus environmental groups can purchase and retire allowances or credits and hence drive up the price of the remainder according to the law of demand.[6] Corporations can also prematurely retire allowances by donating them to a nonprofit entity and then be eligible for a tax deduction.

Definitions

The economics literature provides the following definitions of cap and trade emissions trading schemes.

A cap-and-trade system constrains the aggregate emissions of regulated sources by creating a limited number of tradable emission allowances, which emission sources must secure and surrender in number equal to their emissions.[7]

In an emissions trading or cap-and-trade scheme, a limit on access to a resource (the cap) is defined and then allocated among users in the form of permits. Compliance is established by comparing actual emissions with permits surrendered including any permits traded within the cap.[8]

Under a tradable permit system, an allowable overall level of pollution is established and allocated among firms in the form of permits. Firms that keep their emission levels below their allotted level may sell their surplus permits to other firms or use them to offset excess emissions in other parts of their facilities.[9]

Market-based and least-cost

Economists have urged the use of "market-based" instruments such as emissions trading to address environmental problems instead of prescriptive "command and control" regulation.[10] Command and control regulation is criticized for being excessively rigid, insensitive to geographical and technological differences, and for being inefficient.[11] However, emissions trading requires a cap to effectively reduce emissions, and the cap is a government regulatory mechanism. After a cap has been set by a government political process, individual companies are free to choose how or if they will reduce their emissions. Failure to reduce emissions is often punishable by a further government regulatory mechanism, a fine that increases costs of production. Firms will choose the least-costly way to comply with the pollution regulation, which will lead to reductions where the least expensive solutions exist, while allowing emissions that are more expensive to reduce.

History

The efficiency of what later was to be called the "cap-and-trade" approach to air pollution abatement was first demonstrated in a series of micro-economic computer simulation studies between 1967 and 1970 for the National Air Pollution Control Administration (predecessor to the United States Environmental Protection Agency's Office of Air and Radiation) by Ellison Burton and William Sanjour. These studies used mathematical models of several cities and their emission sources in order to compare the cost and effectiveness of various control strategies.[12][13][14][15][16] Each abatement strategy was compared with the "least cost solution" produced by a computer optimization program to identify the least costly combination of source reductions in order to achieve a given abatement goal.[17] In each case it was found that the least cost solution was dramatically less costly than the same amount of pollution reduction produced by any conventional abatement strategy.[18] This led to the concept of "cap and trade" as a means of achieving the "least cost solution" for a given level of abatement.

The development of emissions trading over the course of its history can be divided into four phases:[19]

  1. Gestation: Theoretical articulation of the instrument (by Coase,[20] Crocker,[21] Dales,[22] Montgomery[23] etc.) and, independent of the former, tinkering with "flexible regulation" at the US Environmental Protection Agency.
  2. Proof of Principle: First developments towards trading of emission certificates based on the "offset-mechanism" taken up in Clean Air Act in 1977.
  3. Prototype: Launching of a first "cap-and-trade" system as part of the US Acid Rain Program in Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act, officially announced as a paradigm shift in environmental policy, as prepared by "Project 88", a network-building effort to bring together environmental and industrial interests in the US.
  4. Regime formation: branching out from the US clean air policy to global climate policy, and from there to the European Union, along with the expectation of an emerging global carbon market and the formation of the "carbon industry".

Comparison of cap-and-trade with other methods of emission reduction

Cap-and-trade, offsets created through a baseline and credit approach, and a carbon tax are all market-based approaches that put a price on carbon and other greenhouse gases and provide an economic incentive to reduce emissions, beginning with the lowest-cost opportunities.

The textbook emissions trading program can be called a "cap-and-trade" approach in which an aggregate cap on all sources is established and these sources are then allowed to trade amongst themselves to determine which sources actually emit the total pollution load. An alternative approach with important differences is a baseline and credit program.[24]

In a baseline and credit program polluters that are not under an aggregate cap can create credits, usually called offsets, by reducing their emissions below a baseline level of emissions. Such credits can be purchased by polluters that do have a regulatory limit.[25]

Economics of international emissions trading

It is possible for a country to reduce emissions using a Command-Control approach, such as regulation, direct and indirect taxes. The cost of that approach differs between countries because the Marginal Abatement Cost Curve (MAC) — the cost of eliminating an additional unit of pollution — differs by country. It might cost China $2 to eliminate a ton of CO2, but it would probably cost Sweden or the U.S. much more. International emissions-trading markets were created precisely to exploit differing MACs.

Example

Emissions trading through Gains from Trade can be more beneficial for both the buyer and the seller than a simple emissions capping scheme.

Consider two European countries, such as Germany and Sweden. Each can either reduce all the required amount of emissions by itself or it can choose to buy or sell in the market.

Example MACs for two different countries

For this example let us assume that Germany can abate its CO2 at a much cheaper cost than Sweden, e.g. MACS > MACG where the MAC curve of Sweden is steeper (higher slope) than that of Germany, and RReq is the total amount of emissions that need to be reduced by a country.

On the left side of the graph is the MAC curve for Germany. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Germany, but at RReq the MACG curve has not intersected the market allowance price of CO2 (market allowance price = P = λ). Thus, given the market price of CO2 allowances, Germany has potential to profit if it abates more emissions than required.

On the right side is the MAC curve for Sweden. RReq is the amount of required reductions for Sweden, but the MACS curve already intersects the market price of CO2 allowances before RReq has been reached. Thus, given the market allowance price of CO2, Sweden has potential to make a cost saving if it abates fewer emissions than required internally, and instead abates them elsewhere.

In this example, Sweden would abate emissions until its MACS intersects with P (at R*), but this would only reduce a fraction of Sweden’s total required abatement. After that it could buy emissions credits from Germany for the price P (per unit). The internal cost of Sweden’s own abatement, combined with the credits it buys in the market from Germany, adds up to the total required reductions (RReq) for Sweden. Thus Sweden can make a saving from buying credits in the market (Δ d-e-f). This represents the "Gains from Trade", the amount of additional expense that Sweden would otherwise have to spend if it abated all of its required emissions by itself without trading.

Germany made a profit on its additional emissions abatement, above what was required: it met the regulations by abating all of the emissions that was required of it (RReq). Additionally, Germany sold its surplus to Sweden as credits, and was paid P for every unit it abated, while spending less than P. Its total revenue is the area of the graph (RReq 1 2 R*), its total abatement cost is area (RReq 3 2 R*), and so its net benefit from selling emission credits is the area (Δ 1-2-3) i.e. Gains from Trade

The two R* (on both graphs) represent the efficient allocations that arise from trading.

  • Germany: sold (R* - RReq) emission credits to Sweden at a unit price P.
  • Sweden bought emission credits from Germany at a unit price P.

If the total cost for reducing a particular amount of emissions in the Command Control scenario is called X, then to reduce the same amount of combined pollution in Sweden and Germany, the total abatement cost would be less in the Emissions Trading scenario i.e. (X — Δ 123 - Δ def).

The example above applies not just at the national level: it applies just as well between two companies in different countries, or between two subsidiaries within the same company.

Applying the economic theory

The nature of the pollutant plays a very important role when policy-makers decide which framework should be used to control pollution.

CO2 acts globally, thus its impact on the environment is generally similar wherever in the globe it is released. So the location of the originator of the emissions does not really matter from an environmental standpoint.

The policy framework should be different for regional pollutants[26] (e.g. SO2 and NOX, and also mercury) because the impact exerted by these pollutants may not be the same in all locations. The same amount of a regional pollutant can exert a very high impact in some locations and a low impact in other locations, so it does actually matter where the pollutant is released. This is known as the Hot Spot problem.

A Lagrange framework is commonly used to determine the least cost of achieving an objective, in this case the total reduction in emissions required in a year. In some cases it is possible to use the Lagrange optimization framework to determine the required reductions for each country (based on their MAC) so that the total cost of reduction is minimized. In such a scenario, the Lagrange multiplier represents the market allowance price (P) of a pollutant, such as the current market allowance price of emissions in Europe and the USA.[27]

Countries face the market allowance price that exists in the market that day, so they are able to make individual decisions that would minimize their costs while at the same time achieving regulatory compliance. This is also another version of the Equi-Marginal Principle, commonly used in economics to choose the most economically efficient decision.

Prices versus quantities, and the safety valve

There has been longstanding debate on the relative merits of price versus quantity instruments to achieve emission reductions.[28]

An emission cap and permit trading system is a quantity instrument because it fixes the overall emission level (quantity) and allows the price to vary. Uncertainty in future supply and demand conditions (market volatility) coupled with a fixed number of pollution credits creates an uncertainty in the future price of pollution credits, and the industry must accordingly bear the cost of adapting to these volatile market conditions. The burden of a volatile market thus lies with the industry rather than the controlling agency, which is generally more efficient. However, under volatile market conditions, the ability of the controlling agency to alter the caps will translate into an ability to pick "winners and losers" and thus presents an opportunity for corruption.

In contrast, an emission tax is a price instrument because it fixes the price while the emission level is allowed to vary according to economic activity. A major drawback of an emission tax is that the environmental outcome (e.g. a limit on the amount of emissions) is not guaranteed. On one hand, a tax will remove capital from the industry, suppressing possibly useful economic activity, but conversely, the polluter will not need to hedge as much against future uncertainty since the amount of tax will track with profits. The burden of a volatile market will be borne by the controlling (taxing) agency rather than the industry itself, which is generally less efficient. An advantage is that, given a uniform tax rate and a volatile market, the taxing entity will not be in a position to pick "winners and losers" and the opportunity for corruption will be less.

Assuming no corruption and assuming that the controlling agency and the industry are equally efficient at adapting to volatile market conditions, the best choice depends on the sensitivity of the costs of emission reduction, compared to the sensitivity of the benefits (i.e., climate damages avoided by a reduction) when the level of emission control is varied.

Because there is high uncertainty in the compliance costs of firms, some argue that the optimum choice is the price mechanism. However, the burden of uncertainty cannot be eliminated, and in this case it is shifted to the taxing agency itself.

Some scientists have warned of a threshold in atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide beyond which a run-away warming effect could take place, with a large possibility of causing irreversible damages. If this is a conceivable risk then a quantity instrument could be a better choice because the quantity of emissions may be capped with a higher degree of certainty. However, this may not be true if this risk exists but cannot be attached to a known level of GHG concentration or a known emission pathway.[29]

A third option, known as a safety valve, is a hybrid of the price and quantity instruments. The system is essentially an emission cap and permit trading system but the maximum (or minimum) permit price is capped. Emitters have the choice of either obtaining permits in the marketplace or purchasing them from the government at a specified trigger price (which could be adjusted over time). The system is sometimes recommended as a way of overcoming the fundamental disadvantages of both systems by giving governments the flexibility to adjust the system as new information comes to light. It can be shown that by setting the trigger price high enough, or the number of permits low enough, the safety valve can be used to mimic either a pure quantity or pure price mechanism.[30]

All three methods are being used as policy instruments to control greenhouse gas emissions: the EU-ETS is a quantity system using the cap and trading system to meet targets set by National Allocation Plans; Denmark has a price system using a carbon tax (World Bank, 2010, p. 218),[31] while China uses the CO2 market price for funding of its Clean Development Mechanism projects, but imposes a safety valve of a minimum price per tonne of CO2.

Carbon leakage

Carbon leakage is the effect that regulation of emissions in one country/sector has on the emissions in other countries/sectors that are not subject to the same regulation (Barker et al.., 2007).[32] There is no consensus over the magnitude of long-term carbon leakage (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 31).[33]

In the Kyoto Protocol, Annex I countries are subject to caps on emissions, but non-Annex I countries are not. Barker et al.. (2007) assessed the literature on leakage. The leakage rate is defined as the increase in CO2 emissions outside of the countries taking domestic mitigation action, divided by the reduction in emissions of countries taking domestic mitigation action. Accordingly, a leakage rate greater than 100% would mean that domestic actions to reduce emissions had had the effect of increasing emissions in other countries to a greater extent, i.e., domestic mitigation action had actually led to an increase in global emissions.

Estimates of leakage rates for action under the Kyoto Protocol ranged from 5 to 20% as a result of a loss in price competitiveness, but these leakage rates were viewed as being very uncertain.[34] For energy-intensive industries, the beneficial effects of Annex I actions through technological development were viewed as possibly being substantial. This beneficial effect, however, had not been reliably quantified. On the empirical evidence they assessed, Barker et al.. (2007) concluded that the competitive losses of then-current mitigation actions, e.g., the EU ETS, were not significant.

Trade

One of the controversies about carbon mitigation policy thus arises about how to "level the playing field" with border adjustments.[35] One component of the American Clean Energy and Security Act, for example, calls for carbon surcharges on goods imported from countries without cap-and-trade programs. Even aside from issues of compliance with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, such border adjustments presume that the producing countries bear responsibility for the carbon emissions.

A general perception among developing countries is that discussion of climate change in trade negotiations could lead to "green protectionism" by high-income countries (World Bank, 2010, p. 251).[31] Tariffs on imports ("virtual carbon") consistent with a carbon price of $50 ton/CO2 could be significant for developing countries. World Bank (2010) commented that introducing border tariffs could lead to a proliferation of trade measures where the competitive playing field is viewed as being uneven. Tariffs could also be a burden on low-income countries that have contributed very little to the problem of climate change.

Trading systems

Kyoto Protocol

The Kyoto Protocol is a 1997 international treaty which came into force in 2005. In the treaty, most developed nations agreed to legally binding targets for their emissions of the six major greenhouse gases.[36] Emission quotas (known as "Assigned amounts") were agreed by each participating 'Annex 1' country, with the intention of reducing the overall emissions by 5.2% from their 1990 levels by the end of 2012. The United States is the only industrialized nation under Annex I that has not ratified the treaty, and is therefore not bound by it. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has projected that the financial effect of compliance through trading within the Kyoto commitment period will be limited at between 0.1-1.1% of GDP among trading countries.[37]

The Protocol defines several mechanisms ("flexible mechanisms") that are designed to allow Annex I countries to meet their emission reduction commitments (caps) with reduced economic impact (IPCC, 2007).[38]

Under Article 3.3 of the Kyoto Protocol, Annex 1 Parties may use GHG removals, from afforestation and reforestation (forest sinks) and deforestation (sources) since 1990, to meet their emission reduction commitments.[39]

Annex 1 Parties may also use International Emissions Trading (IET). Under the treaty, for the 5-year compliance period from 2008 until 2012,[40] nations that emit less than their quota will be able to sell Assigned amount units to nations that exceed their quota.[41] It is also possible for Annex I countries to sponsor carbon projects that reduce greenhouse gas emissions in other countries. These projects generate tradable carbon credits that can be used by Annex I countries in meeting their caps. The project-based Kyoto Mechanisms are the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI).

The CDM covers projects taking place in non-Annex I countries, while JI covers projects taking place in Annex I countries. CDM projects are supposed to contribute to sustainable development in developing countries, and also generate "real" and "additional" emission savings, i.e., savings that only occur thanks to the CDM project in question (Carbon Trust, 2009, p. 14).[42] Whether or not these emission savings are genuine is, however, difficult to prove (World Bank, 2010, pp. 265–267).[31]

Australia

Garnaut Draft Report

In 2003 the New South Wales (NSW) state government unilaterally established the NSW Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme[43] to reduce emissions by requiring electricity generators and large consumers to purchase NSW Greenhouse Abatement Certificates (NGACs). This has prompted the rollout of free energy-efficient compact fluorescent lightbulbs and other energy-efficiency measures, funded by the credits. This scheme has been criticised by the Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM) of the UNSW because of its lack of effectiveness in reducing emissions, its lack of transparency and its lack of verification of the additionality of emission reductions.[44]

On 4 June 2007, former Prime Minister John Howard announced an Australian Carbon Trading Scheme to be introduced by 2012, but opposition parties called the plan "too little, too late".[45] On 24 November 2007 Howard's coalition government lost a general election and was succeeded by the Labor Party, with Kevin Rudd taking over as prime minister. Prime Minister Rudd announced that a cap-and-trade emissions trading scheme would be introduced in 2010,[46] however this scheme was initially delayed by a year to mid-2011,[47] and in May 2010, it was subsequently delayed further until 2013.[48]

Australia's Commonwealth, State and Territory Governments commissioned the Garnaut Climate Change Review, a study by Professor Ross Garnaut on the mechanism of a potential emissions trading scheme. Its interim report was released on 21 February 2008.[49] It recommended an emissions trading scheme that includes transportation but not agriculture, and that emissions permits should be sold competitively and not allocated free to carbon polluters. It recognised that energy prices will increase and that low income families will need to be compensated. It recommended more support for research into low emissions technologies and a new body to oversee such research. It also recognised the need for transition assistance for coal mining areas.[50]

In response to Garnaut's draft report, the Rudd Labor government issued a Green Paper[51] on 16 July that described the intended design of the actual trading scheme.

Subsequent to this, the emission trading scheme proposed by the Government was defeated in the Senate, with the Opposition, the Greens and two independent senators opposing the proposed legislation.[52]

New Zealand

The New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (NZ ETS) is a national all-sectors all-greenhouse gases uncapped emissions trading scheme first legislated in September 2008 by the Fifth Labour Government of New Zealand[53][54] and amended in November 2009 by the Fifth National Government of New Zealand.[55]

Although the NZ ETS covers all-sectors and all-gases, individual sectors of the economy have different entry dates when their obligations to report emissions and surrender emission units have effect. Forestry, a net sink which contributed removals of 14 Mts of CO2e in 2008 or 19% of NZ's 2008 emissions[56], entered on 1 January 2008.[57] Emissions from stationary energy, industrial and liquid fossil fuel sectors (34 Mts in 2008, 45% of 2008 emissions[56], entered the NZ ETS on 1 July 2010. Agricultural emissions (mainly 35 Mts of methane and nitrous oxide emissions from pastoral ruminants or 47% of 2008 emissions[56]) do not enter the scheme until 1 January 2015.[58]

Tradable emission units will be issued by free allocation to emitters, with no auctions in the short term.[59] The fishing sector will receive free units on a historic basis, 90 per cent of their 2005 emissions (bullet points 9 & 10 MfE September 2009[58]). Pre-1990 forests will receive a fixed free allocation of 60 emissions units per hectare.[57] Allocation to emissions-intensive industry,[60] and agriculture[61] will be provided on an output-intensity basis, which will be based on the industry average emissions per unit of output and will be uncapped.[62] Bertram and Terry (2010, p 16 ) state that as there is no 'cap' on emissions, the NZ ETS is not a cap and trade scheme as understood in the economics literature.[63]

A transition period will operate from 1 July 2010 until 31 December 2012. During this period the price of New Zealand Emissions Units (NZUs) will be capped at NZ$25. Also, one unit will only need to be surrendered for every two tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent emissions, effectively reducing the carbon price to NZ$12.50 per tonne (MfE 2009, second bullet point).[58]

Section 3 of the Climate Change Response Act 2002 (the Act) defines the purpose of the Act as to reduce emissions from business-as-usual-levels and to fulfill New Zealand's international obligations under the United Nations Frame Work Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and the Kyoto Protocol.[64] Some stakeholders have criticized the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme for its generous free allocations of emission units and the lack of a carbon price signal (the Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment),[65] and being ineffective in reducing emissions (Greenpeace NZ).[66]

European Union

The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU ETS) is the largest multi-national, greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme in the world. It is one of the EU's central policy instruments to meet their cap set in the Kyoto Protocol (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64).[67]

After voluntary trials in the UK and Denmark, Phase I commenced operation in January 2005 with all 15 (now 25 of the 27) member states of the European Union participating.[68] The program caps the amount of carbon dioxide that can be emitted from large installations with a net heat supply in excess of 20 MW, such as power plants and carbon intensive factories[69] and covers almost half (46%) of the EU's Carbon Dioxide emissions.[70] Phase I permits participants to trade amongst themselves and in validated credits from the developing world through Kyoto's Clean Development Mechanism.

During Phases I and II, allowances for emissions have typically been given free to firms, which has resulted in them getting windfall profits (CCC, 2008, p. 149).[71] Ellerman and Buchner (2008) (referenced by Grubb et al.., 2009, p. 11) suggested that during its first two years in operation, the EU ETS turned an expected increase in emissions of 1-2 percent per year into a small absolute decline.[72] Grubb et al.. (2009, p. 11) suggested that a reasonable estimate for the emissions cut achieved during its first two years of operation was 50-100 MtCO2 per year, or 2.5-5 percent.

A number of design flaws have limited the effectiveness of scheme (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64). In the initial 2005-07 period, emission caps were not tight enough to drive a significant reduction in emissions (CCC, 2008, p. 149). The total allocation of allowances turned out to exceed actual emissions. This drove the carbon price down to zero in 2007. This oversupply reflects the difficulty in predicting future emissions which is necessary in setting a cap.

Phase II saw some tightening, but the use of JI and CDM offsets was allowed, with the result that no reductions in the EU will be required to meet the Phase II cap (CCC, 2008, pp. 145, 149). For Phase II, the cap is expected to result in an emissions reduction in 2010 of about 2.4% compared to expected emissions without the cap (business-as-usual emissions) (Jones et al.., 2007, p. 64). For Phase III (2013–20), the European Commission has proposed a number of changes, including:

  • the setting an overall EU cap, with allowances then allocated to EU members;
  • tighter limits on the use of offsets;
  • unlimiting banking of allowances between Phases II and III;
  • and a move from allowances to auctioning.

In January 2008 Norway, Iceland, and Lichtenstein, joined the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) according to a publication from the European Commission.[73] The Norwegian Ministry of the Environment has also released its draft National Allocation Plan which provides a carbon cap-and-trade of 15 million metric tonnes of CO2, 8 million of which are set to be auctioned.[74][citation needed] According to the OECD Economic Survey of Norway 2010, the nation "has announced a target for 2008-12 10% below its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol and a 30% cut compared with 1990 by 2020." [75]

Tokyo, Japan

The Japanese city of Tokyo is like a country in its own right in terms of its energy consumption and GDP. Tokyo consumes as much energy as "entire countries in Northern Europe, and its production matches the GNP of the world’s 16th largest country".[76] Originally, Japan had its own cap and trade system that had been in place for some years, but was not effective.[77] Japan has its own emission reduction policy but not a nationwide cap and trade program. This climate strategy is enforced and overseen by the Tokyo Metropolitan Government (TMG).[78] The first phase, which is alike to Japan's scheme, runs up to 2014, these organizations will have to cut their carbon emissions by 6%; those who fail to operate within their emission caps will from 2011 on be required to purchase emission allowances to cover any excess emissions, or alternatively, invest in renewable energy certificates or offset credits issued by smaller businesses or branch offices.[79] Firms whom fail to comply will face fines. According to local reports, organizations that do not operate within their caps will also be ordered to cut emissions by 1.3 times the amount they failed to reduce during the first phase of the scheme. The long term aim is to cut the metropolis' carbon emissions by 25% from 2000 levels by 2020.[80]

United States

An early example of an emission trading system has been the SO2 trading system under the framework of the Acid Rain Program of the 1990 Clean Air Act in the U.S. Under the program, which is essentially a cap-and-trade emissions trading system, SO2 emissions were reduced by 50% from 1980 levels by 2007.[81] Some experts argue that the cap-and-trade system of SO2 emissions reduction has reduced the cost of controlling acid rain by as much as 80% versus source-by-source reduction.[10][82]

In 1997, the State of Illinois adopted a trading program for volatile organic compounds in most of the Chicago area, called the Emissions Reduction Market System.[83] Beginning in 2000, over 100 major sources of pollution in eight Illinois counties began trading pollution credits.

In 2003, New York State proposed and attained commitments from nine Northeast states to form a cap-and-trade carbon dioxide emissions program for power generators, called the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). This program launched on January 1, 2009 with the aim to reduce the carbon "budget" of each state's electricity generation sector to 10% below their 2009 allowances by 2018.[84]

Also in 2003, U.S. corporations were able to trade CO2 emission allowances on the Chicago Climate Exchange under a voluntary scheme. In August 2007, the Exchange announced a mechanism to create emission offsets for projects within the United States that cleanly destroy ozone-depleting substances.[85]

Also in 2003, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) began to administer the NOx Budget Trading Program (NBP)under the NOx State Implementation Plan (also known as the “NOx SIP Call”) The NOx Budget Trading Program was a market-based cap and trade program created to reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides (NOx) from power plants and other large combustion sources in the eastern United States. NOx is a prime ingredient in the formation of ground-level ozone (smog), a pervasive air pollution problem in many areas of the eastern United States. The NBP was designed to reduce NOx emissions during the warm summer months, referred to as the ozone season, when ground-level ozone concentrations are highest. In March 2008, EPA again strengthened the 8-hour ozone standard to 0.075 parts per million (ppm) from its previous 0.008 ppm.[86]

In 2006, the California Legislature passed the California Global Warming Solutions Act, AB-32, which was signed into law by Governor Arnold Schwarzenegger. Thus far, flexible mechanisms in the form of project based offsets have been suggested for five main project types. A carbon project would create offsets by showing that it has reduced carbon dioxide and equivalent gases. The project types include: manure management, forestry, building energy, SF6, and landfill gas capture.

Since February 2007, seven U.S. states and four Canadian provinces have joined together to create the Western Climate Initiative (WCI),a regional greenhouse gas emissions trading system.[87] July 2010, a meeting took place to further outlined the cap-and-trade system which if accepted would curb greenhouse gas emissions by January 2012.[88]

On November 17, 2008 President-elect Barack Obama clarified, in a talk recorded for YouTube, that the US will enter a cap-and-trade system to limit global warming.[89]

The 2010 United States federal budget proposes to support clean energy development with a 10-year investment of US $15 billion per year, generated from the sale of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions credits. Under the proposed cap-and-trade program, all GHG emissions credits would be auctioned off, generating an estimated $78.7 billion in additional revenue in FY 2012, steadily increasing to $83 billion by FY 2019.[90]

The American Clean Energy and Security Act(H.R. 2454) , a cap-and-trade bill, was passed on June 26, 2009, in the House of Representatives by a vote of 219-212. The bill originated in the House Energy and Commerce Committee and was introduced by Rep. Henry A. Waxman and Rep. Edward J. Markey.[91]

Renewable energy certificates

Renewable Energy Certificates, or "green tags", are transferable rights for renewable energy within some American states. A renewable energy provider gets issued one green tag for each 1,000 kWh of energy it produces. The energy is sold into the electrical grid, and the certificates can be sold on the open market for profit. They are purchased by firms or individuals in order to identify a portion of their energy with renewable sources and are voluntary.

They are typically used like an offsetting scheme or to show corporate responsibility, although their issuance is unregulated, with no national registry to ensure there is no double-counting. However, it is one way that an organization could purchase its energy from a local provider who uses fossil fuels, but back it with a certificate that supports a specific wind or hydro power project.

Carbon market

Carbon emissions trading is emissions trading specifically for carbon dioxide (calculated in tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent or tCO2e) and currently makes up the bulk of emissions trading. It is one of the ways countries can meet their obligations under the Kyoto Protocol to reduce carbon emissions and thereby mitigate global warming.

Market trend

Carbon emissions trading has been steadily increasing in recent years. According to the World Bank's Carbon Finance Unit, 374 million metric tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (tCO2e) were exchanged through projects in 2005, a 240% increase relative to 2004 (110 mtCO2e)[92] which was itself a 41% increase relative to 2003 (78 mtCO2e).[93]

In terms of dollars, Felipe de Jesus Garduño Vazquez uses the World Bank has estimated that the size of the carbon market was 11 billion USD in 2005, 30 billion USD in 2006,[92] and 64 billion in 2007.[94]

The Marrakesh Accords of the Kyoto protocol defined the international trading mechanisms and registries needed to support trading between countries, with allowance trading now occurring between European countries and Asian countries. However, while the USA as a nation did not ratify the Protocol, many of its states are now developing cap-and-trade systems and are looking at ways to link their emissions trading systems together, nationally and internationally, to seek out the lowest costs and improve liquidity of the market.[95] However, these states also wish to preserve their individual integrity and unique features. For example, in contrast to the other Kyoto-compliant systems, some states propose other types of greenhouse gas sources, different measurement methods, setting a maximum on the price of allowances, or restricting access to CDM projects. Creating instruments that are not truly fungible would introduce instability and make pricing difficult. Various proposals are being investigated to see how these systems might be linked across markets, with the International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP) as an international body to help co-ordinate this.[96][97]

Business reaction

With the creation of a market for mandatory trading of carbon dioxide emissions within the Kyoto Protocol, the London financial marketplace has established itself as the center of the carbon finance market, and is expected to have grown into a market valued at $60 billion in 2007.[98] The voluntary offset market, by comparison, is projected to grow to about $4bn by 2010.[99]

23 multinational corporations came together in the G8 Climate Change Roundtable, a business group formed at the January 2005 World Economic Forum. The group included Ford, Toyota, British Airways, BP and Unilever. On June 9, 2005 the Group published a statement stating that there was a need to act on climate change and stressing the importance of market-based solutions. It called on governments to establish "clear, transparent, and consistent price signals" through "creation of a long-term policy framework" that would include all major producers of greenhouse gases.[100] By December 2007 this had grown to encompass 150 global businesses.[101]

Business in the UK have come out strongly in support of emissions trading as a key tool to mitigate climate change, supported by NGOs.[102] However, not all businesses favor a trading approach. On December 11, 2008, Rex Tillerson, the CEO of Exxonmobil, said a carbon tax is "a more direct, more transparent and more effective approach" than a cap-and-trade program, which he said, "inevitably introduces unnecessary cost and complexity". He also said that he hoped that the revenues from a carbon tax would be used to lower other taxes so as to be revenue neutral.[103]

The International Air Transport Association, whose 230 member airlines comprise 93% of all international traffic, position is that trading should be based on “benchmarking,” setting emissions levels based on industry averages, rather than “grandfathering,” which would use individual companies’ previous emissions levels to set their future permit allowances. They argue grandfathering “would penalise airlines that took early action to modernise their fleets, while a benchmarking approach, if designed properly, would reward more efficient operations".[104]

Measuring, reporting, verification (MRV)

An emissions trading system requires measurements at the level of operator or installation. These measurements are then reported to a regulator. For greenhouse gases all trading countries maintain an inventory of emissions at national and installation level; in addition, the trading groups within North America maintain inventories at the state level through The Climate Registry. For trading between regions these inventories must be consistent, with equivalent units and measurement techniques.

In some industrial processes emissions can be physically measured by inserting sensors and flowmeters in chimneys and stacks, but many types of activity rely on theoretical calculations for measurement. Depending on local legislation, these measurements may require additional checks and verification by government or third party auditors, prior or post submission to the local regulator.

Enforcement

Another significant, yet troublesome aspect is enforcement.[105] Without effective MRV and enforcement the value of allowances are diminished. Enforcement can be done using several means, including fines or sanctioning those that have exceeded their allowances. Concerns include the cost of MRV and enforcement and the risk that facilities may be tempted to mislead rather than make real reductions or make up their shortfall by purchasing allowances or offsets from another entity. The net effect of a corrupt reporting system or poorly managed or financed regulator may be a discount on emission costs, and a (hidden) increase in actual emissions.

According to Nordhaus (2007, p. 27), strict enforcement of the Kyoto Protocol is likely to be observed in those countries and industries covered by the EU ETS.[106] Ellerman and Buchner (2007, p. 71) commented on the European Commission's (EC's) role in enforcing scarcity of permits within the EU ETS.[107] This was done by the EC's reviewing the total number of permits that member states proposed that their industries be allocated. Based on institutional and enforcement considerations, Kruger et al. (2007, pp. 130–131) suggested that emissions trading within developing countries might not be a realistic goal in the near-term.[108] Burniaux et al.. (2008, p. 56) argued that due to the difficulty in enforcing international rules against sovereign states, development of the carbon market would require negotiation and consensus-building.[109]

Views on emissions trading

Chicago Climate Justice activists protesting cap and trade legislation in front of Chicago Climate Exchange building in Chicago Loop

Criticisms

Emissions trading has been criticised for a variety of reasons.

In the popular science magazine New Scientist, Lohmann (2006) argued that trading pollution allowances should be avoided as a climate change policy. Lohman gave these reasons for this view. First, global warming will require more radical change than the modest changes driven by previous pollution trading schemes such as the US SO2 market. Global warming requires “nothing less than a reorganisation of society and technology that will leave most remaining fossil fuels safely underground ”. Carbon trading schemes have tended to reward the heaviest polluters with 'windfall profits' when they are granted enough carbon credits to match historic production. Carbon trading encourages business-as-usual as expensive long-term structural changes won't be made if there is a cheaper source of carbon credits. Cheap "offset" carbon credits are frequently available from the less developed countries, where they may be generated by local polluters at the expense of local communities.[110]

Lohmann (2006b) supported conventional regulation, green taxes, and energy policies that are "justice-based" and "community-driven."[111] According to Carbon Trade Watch (2009), carbon trading has had a "disastrous track record." The effectiveness of the EU ETS was criticized, and it was argued that the CDM had routinely favoured "environmentally ineffective and socially unjust projects."[112]

Annie Leonard provided a critical view on carbon emissions trading in her 2009 documentary The Story of Cap and Trade. This documentary emphasized three factors: unjust financial advantages to major pollutors resulting from free permits, an ineffectiveness of the system caused by cheating in connection with carbon offsets and a distraction from the search for other solutions.

Offsets

Forest campaigner Jutta Kill (2006) of European environmental group FERN argued that offsets for emission reductions were no substitute for actual cuts in emissions. Kill stated that "[carbon] in trees is temporary: Trees can easily release carbon into the atmosphere through fire, disease, climatic changes, natural decay and timber harvesting."[113]

Supply of permits

Regulatory agencies run the risk of issuing too many emission credits, which can result in a very low price on emission permits (CCC, 2008, p. 140).[71] This reduces the incentive that permit-liable firms have to cut back their emissions. On the other hand, issuing too few permits can result in an excessively high permit price (Hepburn, 2006, p. 239).[114] This is one of the arguments in favour of a hybrid instrument, that has a price-floor, i.e., a minimum permit price, and a price-ceiling, i.e., a limit on the permit price. A price-ceiling (safety value) does, however, remove the certainty of a particular quantity limit of emissions (Bashmakov et al.., 2001).[115]

Incentives

Emissions trading can result in perverse incentives. If, for example, polluting firms are given emission permits for free ("grandfathering"), this may create a reason for them not to cut their emissions. This is because a firm making large cuts in emissions would then potentially be granted fewer emission permits in the future (IMF, 2008, pp. 25–26).[116] This perverse incentive can be alleviated if permits are auctioned, i.e., sold to polluters, rather than giving them the permits for free (Hepburn, 2006, pp. 236–237).[114]

On the other hand, allocating permits can be used as a measure to protect domestic firms who are internationally exposed to competition (p. 237). This happens when domestic firms compete against other firms that are not subject to the same regulation. This argument in favour of allocation of permits has been used in the EU ETS, where industries that have been judged to be internationally exposed, e.g., cement and steel production, have been given permits for free (4CMR, 2008).[117]

Auctioning

The revenues from auctioning go to the government. These revenues could, for example, be used for research and development of sustainable technology.[118] Alternatively, revenues could be used to cut distortionary taxes, thus improving the efficiency of the overall cap policy (Fisher et al.., 1996, p. 417).[119]

Distributional effects

The Congressional Budget Office (CBO, 2009) examined the potential effects of the American Clean Energy and Security Act on US households.[120] This Act relies heavily on the free allocation of permits. The Bill was found to protect low-income consumers, but it was recommended that the Bill be changed to be more efficient. It was suggested that the Bill be changed to reduce welfare provisions for corporations, and more resources be made available for consumer relief.

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N. (November 2001). "Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments" (Document). Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. Market-based instruments are regulations that encourage behavior through market signals rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods {{cite document}}: Unknown parameter |accessdate= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |url= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |work= ignored (help)
  2. ^ Montgomery, W.D. "Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs". Journal of Economic Theory 5 (December 1972):395-418
  3. ^ EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS). UK Department of Energy and Climate Change. Retrieved 2009-01-19.
  4. ^ "USEPA's Clean Air Markets web site". US EPA. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  5. ^ a b Cap and Trade 101, Center for American Progress, January 16, 2008.
  6. ^ Sullivan, Arthur, and Steven M. Sheffrin. Economics: Principles in action. Upper Saddle River, NJ, 2003. ISBN 0130630853
  7. ^ Judson Jaffe, Matthew Ranson and Robert N. Stavins (2009). "Linking Tradable Permit Systems: A Key Element of Emerging International Climate Policy Architecture" (PDF). Ecology Law Quarterly. 36 (789). Retrieved 2010-08-25.
  8. ^ Tietenberg Tom (2003). "The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change". Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 19 (3): 400–419. Retrieved 2010-08-25.
  9. ^ Stavins, Robert N. (2001). "Experience with Market-Based Environmental Policy Instruments" (Document). Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future. {{cite document}}: Unknown parameter |accessdate= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |series= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |url= ignored (help)
  10. ^ a b Stavins, Robert N (1998). "What Can We Learn from the Grand Policy Experiment? Lessons from SO2 Allowance Trading". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3. 12 (3). American Economic Association: 69–88.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  11. ^ Bryner, Gary C. Blue Skies, Green Politics: the Clean Air Act of 1990. Washington D.C.:Congressional Quarterly Inc., 1951.
  12. ^ Burton, Ellison; Sanjour, William (1967). "An Economic Analysis of the Control of Sulphur Oxides Air Pollution". DHEW Program Analysis Report No. 1967-69. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  13. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1968). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Particulate and SOx Emission Control in the New York Metropolitan Area. NTIS: PB-227 121/1. Contract Number: PH-86-68-37. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
  14. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-Effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the Greater Kansas City Area. NTIS: PB-227 116/1. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
  15. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1969). A Cost-effectiveness Study of Air Pollution Abatement in the National Capital Area. NAPCA Contract No. PH 86-68-37, NTIS: PB227110. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
  16. ^ Burton, Ellison, and William Sanjour. (1970). Applications of Cost-effectiveness Analysis to Air Pollution Control. DHEW Contract No. CPA 22-69-17. Washington, DC: Ernst and Ernst.
  17. ^ Burton, Ellison; Sanjour, William (1969-03). "Multiple Source Analysis of Air Pollution Abatement Strategies" (PDF). Federal Accountant. XVIII: 48–69. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  18. ^ Burton, E. S.; William (1970). "A Simulation Approach to Air Pollution Abatement Program Planning" (PDF). Socio-Economic Planning Science. 4: 147–150. doi:10.1016/0038-0121(70)90036-4. {{cite journal}}: Unknown parameter |unused_data= ignored (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  19. ^ Voss, Jan-Peter (2007-06). "Innovation processes in governance: the development of emissions trading as a new policy instrument". Science and Public Policy. 5. 34. Ingentaconnect: 329–343. doi:10.3152/030234207X228584. Retrieved 2009-11-03. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  20. ^ Coase, Ronald H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics. 3:1-44.
  21. ^ Crocker, T. D. (1966). The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems. The Economics of Air Pollution. H. Wolozin. New York, W. W. Norton & Co.: 61-86.
  22. ^ Dales, John H. 1968. Land, Water, and Ownership. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 1(4):791-804.
  23. ^ Montgomery, W David. 1972. Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs, Journal of Economic Theory 5(3):395-418.
  24. ^ Tietenberg, Tom; Johnstone, Nick (2004). "ExPost Evaluation of Tradeable Permits: Methodological Issues and Literature Review". Tradeable Permits: Policy Evaluation, Design And Reform. OECD Publishing. ISBN 9789264015029.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  25. ^ Chomitz, Kenneth M (1999). (Document). The World Bank. {{cite document}}: Missing or empty |title= (help); Unknown parameter |contribution= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |series= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |url= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |volume= ignored (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  26. ^ Map: Pollution hotspots, BBC map of areas that suffer from intense local pollution, BBC News, 2004-12-13. Retrieved 2009-10-19.
  27. ^ "Chicago Climate Exchange prices". Chicagoclimatex.com. 2009-08-04. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  28. ^ Weitzman, M. L. (1974-10)). "Prices vs. Quantities". The Review of Economic Studies. 41 (4). The Review of Economic Studies Ltd.: 477–491. doi:10.2307/2296698. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  29. ^ Philibert, Cédric (2006-10). "Certainty versus ambition economic efficiency in mitigating climate change" (PDF). International Energy Agency Working Paper Series. LTO/2006/03. Paris: International Energy Agency/OECD. Retrieved 2010-01-24. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  30. ^ Jacoby, D.H.; Ellerman, A.D. (2004-03). "The safety valve and climate policy". Energy Policy. 32 (4). Sciencedirect.com: 481–49. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00150-2. Retrieved 2009-11-03. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  31. ^ a b c World Bank (2010). "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change". The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433. Retrieved 2010-04-06.
  32. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "11.7.2 Carbon leakage. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In (book): Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-05. {{cite web}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  33. ^ Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). Introduction: scope of the assessment. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. Eds.) (PDF). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. {{cite book}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  34. ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Executive Summary. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. In (book): Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-05. {{cite web}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  35. ^ Houser, Trevor (2008). Leveling The Carbon Playing Field: International Competition and U.S. Climate Policy Design. Peterson Institute for International Economics. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  36. ^ "Kyoto Protocol". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2009-09-16.
  37. ^ "Climate Change 2007: Mitigation of Climate Change, Summary for Policymakers from [[IPCC Fourth Assessment Report]]" (PDF). Working Group III, IPCC. 2007-05-04. pp. Item 25, page 33. Retrieved 2007-05-10. {{cite web}}: URL–wikilink conflict (help)
  38. ^ IPCC (2007). "Glossary J-P. In (book section): Annex I. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Retrieved 2010-04-23.
  39. ^ "LULUCF under the Kyoto Protocol". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-28.
  40. ^ "UNFCCC Countries 1990 to 2012 emissions targets". UNFCCC website. 2008-05-14. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  41. ^ "Emissions Trading". UNFCCC website. Retrieved 2009-09-16.
  42. ^ Carbon Trust (March 2009). "Global Carbon Mechanisms: Emerging lessons and implications (CTC748)". Carbon Trust website. Retrieved 2010-03-31.
  43. ^ "The Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme". NSW: Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme Administrator. 2010-01-04. Retrieved 2010-01-16.
  44. ^ Passey, Rob; MacGill, Iain; Outhred, Hugh (2007). "The NSW Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme: An analysis of the NGAC Registry for the 2003, 2004 and 2005 Compliance Periods". (Document). Sydney: The UNSW Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM). {{cite document}}: Missing or empty |title= (help); Unknown parameter |accessdate= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |contribution-url= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |series= ignored (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  45. ^ Farr, Malcolm (2007-06-04). "Howard flying blind on climate". Herald Sun. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  46. ^ "Australian Carbon Trade to Boost Affordable Energy". Planet Ark. 2008-06-24. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  47. ^ Smith, Peter (2009-05-05). "Rudd delays carbon trading". The Financial Times. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  48. ^ "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme" (Press release). Department of Climate Change and Energy Efficiency. 2010-05-05. Retrieved 2010-06-14.
  49. ^ "Garnaut Climate Change Review" (PDF). Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  50. ^ "Garnaut Review". Garnaut Review. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  51. ^ "Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme Green Paper". Greenhouse.gov.au. 2009-10-14. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  52. ^ Emma Rodgers (2009-12-02). "Senate kills off emissions trade laws". Australian Broadcasting Corporation. Retrieved 2010-07-29.
  53. ^ Parker, David (2008-09-10). "Historic climate change legislation passes". New Zealand Government Media Release. Retrieved 2008-09-10.
  54. ^ "Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 No 85". www.legislation.govt.nz. Parliamentary Counsel Office. 2008-09-25. Retrieved 2010-01-25.
  55. ^ Nick Smith (2009-11-25). "Balanced new law important step on climate change". New Zealand Government Press Release. Retrieved 2010-06-14.
  56. ^ a b c MfE (April 2010). "New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2008" (Document). Ministry for the Environment. {{cite document}}: Unknown parameter |accessdate= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |issn= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |series= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |url= ignored (help)
  57. ^ a b MfE (2010-01-14). "How will the changes impact on forestry?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). Retrieved 2010-05-16.
  58. ^ a b c MfE (September 2009). "Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS". Emissions trading bulletin No 11. Ministry for the Environment (MfE), NZ Government. Retrieved 2010-05-15.
  59. ^ "New Zealand Units (NZUs)". Climate change information New Zealand. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). 2010-06-18. Retrieved 2010-08-13. In the short term, the Government is unlikely to sell emission units because the Kyoto units allocated to New Zealand will be needed to support New Zealand's international obligations, as well as allocation to eligible sectors under the emissions trading scheme.
  60. ^ "Who will get a free allocation of emission units?". Questions and answers about the emissions trading scheme. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). 2010-01-14. Retrieved 2010-05-15.
  61. ^ MfE (September 2009). "Agriculture". Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS - Emissions Trading Bulletin 11. Ministry for the Environment. Retrieved 2010-05-16.
  62. ^ MfE (2010-01-14). "How will free allocation of emission units to the industrial sector work now?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). Retrieved 2010-05-16.
  63. ^ Bertram, Geoff; Terry, Simon (2010). The Carbon Challenge: New Zealand’s Emissions Trading Scheme. Bridget Williams Books, Wellington. ISBN 978-1-877242-46-5. The New Zealand ETS does not fit this model because there is no cap and therefore no certainty as to the volume of emissions with which the national economy must operate
  64. ^ "Climate Change Response Act 2002 No 40 (as at 08 December 2009), Public Act – New Zealand Legislation". NZ Parliamentary Counsel Office/Te Tari Tohutohu Pa-remata. Retrieved 2010-05-14.
  65. ^ "New bill 'weakens ETS' says Environment Commissioner" (Press release). Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment. 2009-10-15. Retrieved 2009-10-15. The allocation of free carbon credits to industrial processes is extremely generous and removes the carbon price signal where New Zealand needs one the most
  66. ^ "Revised ETS an insult to New Zealanders" (Press release). Greenpeace New Zealand. 2009-09-14. Retrieved 2009-10-12. We now have on the table a pathetic ETS which won't actually do anything to reduce emissions
  67. ^ Jones, B.; et al. (2007), "Appendix 1.2 Climate Change: Economic Impact and Policy Responses.", Chapter 1. Global Prospects and Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys, World Economic Outlook, Globalization and Inequality, IMF, retrieved 2010-04-26 {{citation}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  68. ^ Climate Change: The European Union's Emissions Trading System (EU ETS)[dead link]
  69. ^ "Britain, California to join forces on global warming". The Washington Times. 2006-07-31. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  70. ^ Wagner, M.: Firms, the Framework Convention on Climate Change & the EU Emissions Trading System. Corporate Energy Management Strategies to Address Climate Change and GHG Emissions in the European Union. Lüneburg: Centre for Sustainability Management 2004, p.12 [1] CSM Lüneburg
  71. ^ a b CCC (December 2008). "Chapter 4: Carbon markets and carbon prices. In: Building a low-carbon economy – The UK's contribution to tackling climate change. The First Report of the Committee on Climate Change. December 2008". Print version: The Stationary Office. This version: CCC website. Retrieved 2010-04-26. {{cite web}}: External link in |publisher= (help)
  72. ^ Grubb, M.; et al. (3 August 2009). "Climate Policy and Industrial Competitiveness: Ten Insights from Europe on the EU Emissions Trading System". Climate Strategies. Retrieved 2010-04-14. {{cite web}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  73. ^ IEA (2007). "European Commission Environment - EU action against climate change" (PDF). European Commission Environment. p. 24. Retrieved 2010-08-01.
  74. ^ Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2007). "The Norwegian Government accepts to include the EU Emissions Trading Directive in the EEA agreement". European Commission Environment. p. 24. Retrieved 2010-08-03.
  75. ^ Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (2010). "Economic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policiesEconomic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policies". Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. pp. n/a. Retrieved 2010-08-03.
  76. ^ "Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program". Artcraft Japan For your Japanese Heart and Soul. 2010-07-16. Retrieved 2010-08-05.
  77. ^ "Tokyo emissions trading plan may become a model for others". World Council for Sustainable Development. 2010-02-111. Retrieved 2010-08-12. {{cite web}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  78. ^ Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program, Artcraft Japan For your Japanese Heart and Soul, July 16, 2010.
  79. ^ Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme, April, 2010.
  80. ^ [Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme, April, 2010.
  81. ^ Acid Rain Program 2007 Progress Report, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, January 2009.
  82. ^ Carlson, Curtis, Dallas Burtraw, Maureen Cropper, and Karen L. Palmer. 2000. “Sulfur dioxide control by electric utilities: What are the gains from trade?” Journal of Political Economy 108: 1292-1326.
  83. ^ "Emissions Reduction Market System What Is ERMS?". Illinois EPA. 2007.
  84. ^ Memorandum of Understanding - Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
  85. ^ Beyond the Kyoto six Carbon Finance 7 March 2008
  86. ^ [2], Environmental Protection Agency, August 13, 2010
  87. ^ [3] Western Climate Initiative}
  88. ^ California, New Mexico and 3 Canadian provinces outline regional cap-and-trade program, Los Angeles Times, July 28, 2010
  89. ^ 17 novembre 2008. "YouTube — A New Chapter on Climate Change". It.youtube.com. Retrieved 2009-04-03.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  90. ^ "President's Budget Draws Clean Energy Funds from Climate Measure". Renewable Energy World. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  91. ^ "The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454)". Energycommerce.house.gov. 2009-06-01. Retrieved 2010-06-14.
  92. ^ a b "Carbon Finance" (PDF). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  93. ^ "Microsoft Word — Carbon Market Study 2005 - FINAL — Letter.doc" (PDF). Carbonfinance.org. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  94. ^ "Carbon Finance" (PDF). Carbon Finance. 2009-01-15. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  95. ^ Stavins, Robert N., and Judson Jaffe (2008). Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture, Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements. [4]
  96. ^ International Carbon Action Partnership ICAP website
  97. ^ Linkage of Tradable Permit Systems in International Climate Policy Architecture Robert N. Stavins and Judson Jaffe, Harvard Project on International Climate Agreements
  98. ^ "Point Carbon news". Pointcarbon.com. Retrieved 2009-11-03.
  99. ^ The carbon market Fiona Harvey, FT April 27, 2007
  100. ^ http://www.weforum.org/pdf/g8_climatechange.pdf
  101. ^ List of climate leaders EPA December 12
  102. ^ "Meeting the Energy Challenge A White Paper on Energy May 2007" (Document). UK Department of Trade and Industry. {{cite document}}: Unknown parameter |accessdate= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |contribution-url= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |contribution= ignored (help); Unknown parameter |format= ignored (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  103. ^ "Exxon supports carbon tax". Calgary Herald News. 2009-01-09.
  104. ^ "What You Need to Know About Emissions Trading" (PDF). International Air Transport Association. Retrieved 2009-09-26.
  105. ^ Ott, Hermann E. (1998-10-26). "Emissions Trading in the Kyoto Protocol, Finished and Unfinished Business". Linkages Journal. 4. 3.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  106. ^ Nordhaus, W.D. (2007). "To Tax of Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  107. ^ Ellerman, A.D. and B.K. Buchner (2007). "The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  108. ^ Kruger, J.; et al. (2007). "Decentralization in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme and Lessons for Global Policy" (PDF). Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1 (1). Retrieved 2010-04-28. {{cite journal}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  109. ^ Burniaux, J-M.; et al. (6 June 2009). "The Economics of Climate Change Mitigation: How to Build the Necessary Global Action in a Cost-Effective Manner. Economics Department Working Papers No. 701". OECD website. Retrieved 2010-04-24. {{cite web}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  110. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006-12-05). "A licence to carry on polluting?". New Scientist. 2580. Archived from the original on 2006-12-05. Retrieved 2010-07-17.
  111. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006b). "Ways forward (The Corner House)". The Corner House. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  112. ^ Carbon Trade Watch (November 2009). "Carbon Trading – How it works and why it fails". Dag Hammerskjold Foundation. Retrieved 2010-08-04.
  113. ^ Kill, J. (July 2006). "10 things you should know about tree 'offsets'". New Internationalist. Retrieved 2010-04-28.
  114. ^ a b Hepburn, C. (2006). "Regulating by prices, quantities or both: an update and an overview" (PDF). Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 22 (2): 226–247. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grj014. Retrieved August 30, 2009.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: postscript (link)
  115. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "6.2.2.3 Tradable Permits. In (book chapter): 6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Retrieved 2010-04-26. {{cite web}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help); External link in |publisher= (help)
  116. ^ IMF (March 2008). "Fiscal Implications of Climate Change" (PDF). International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department. Retrieved 2010-04-26.
  117. ^ 4CMR (19 June 2008). "Memorandum by the Cambridge Centre for Climate Change Mitigation Research. European Union – Minutes of Evidence, Wednesday 8 October 2008. European Union Committee, Session 2007-2008, Thirty-third Report: The Revision of the EU's Emissions Trading System". UK Parliament website. Retrieved 2010-04-28.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  118. ^ "Climate change; The greening of America". The Economist. 2007-01-25. Retrieved 2009-04-03.
  119. ^ Fisher, B.S.; et al. (1996). An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. Eds.) (PDF). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K., and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 9780521568548. {{cite book}}: Explicit use of et al. in: |author= (help)
  120. ^ Stone, Chad; Shaw, Hannah (2009-07-10). "Senate can strengthen climate legislation by reducing corporate welfare and boosting true consumer relief" (PDF). Centre for Budget and Policy Priorities. Retrieved 2010-01-27.

Further reading

External links