George Stigler

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by EmausBot (talk | contribs) at 10:06, 12 February 2011 (r2.6.4) (robot Adding: yo:George Stigler). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

George Stigler
Born(1911-01-17)January 17, 1911
Seattle, Washington
DiedDecember 1, 1991(1991-12-01) (aged 80)
Chicago, Illinois
NationalityUnited States
Academic career
InstitutionColumbia University
Brown University
University of Chicago
FieldEconomics
School or
tradition
Chicago School of Economics
Alma materUniversity of Chicago (Ph.D.), University of Washington (BA), Northwestern University
InfluencesFrank Knight, Jacob Viner, Henry Simons, Milton Friedman
ContributionsCapture theory
AwardsNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (1982)
National Medal of Science (1987)

George Joseph Stigler (January 17, 1911 – December 1, 1991) was a U.S. economist. He won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1982, and was a key leader of the Chicago School of Economics, along with his close friend Milton Friedman.

While at Chicago, he was greatly influenced by Frank Knight, his dissertation supervisor. Friedman, a friend for over sixty years, comments upon it as remarkable since only three or four students ever managed to complete their PhD dissertation under Knight in his 28 years at Chicago. Jacob Viner and Henry Simons also influenced him and, among his students, W. Allen Wallis and Milton Friedman.

Stigler is best known for developing the Economic Theory of Regulation, also known as capture, which says that interest groups and other political participants will use the regulatory and coercive powers of government to shape laws and regulations in a way that is beneficial to them. This theory is a component of the public choice field of economics. He also carried out extensive research in the history of economic thought.

Stigler's most important contribution to economics was disseminated in his landmark article titled "The Economics of Information".[1] According to Friedman, Stigler "essentially created a new area of study for economists." In this article, Stigler stressed the importance of information by writing, "One should hardly have to tell academicians that information is a valuable resource: knowledge is power. And yet it occupies a slum dwelling in the town of economics."[2]

His 1962 article "Information in the Labor Market" developed the theory of search unemployment.[3]

He was known for his sharp sense of humor, and wrote a number of spoof essays. In his book The Intellectual and the Marketplace, for instance, he proposed Stigler's Law of Demand and Supply Elasticities, that "all demand curves are inelastic and all supply curves are inelastic too." The essay referenced studies that found many goods and services to be inelastic over the long run, as well as offering a supposed theoretical proof; he ended by announcing that his next essay would demonstrate that the price system does not exist. Another essay, on "Truth in Teaching," described the consequences of a (fictional) set of court decisions that held universities legally responsible for the consequences of teaching errors.[4]

The Stigler diet was named after him.

Stigler was born in Seattle, Washington, graduated from the University of Washington in 1931 with a B.A and then spent a year at Northwestern University from which he obtained his M.B.A in 1932. It was during his studies at Northwestern that Stigler developed an interest in economics and decided on an academic career.[2]

Due to a tuition scholarship that he received from the University of Chicago, Stigler enrolled at the university in 1933 to study economics and went on to earn his Ph.D. in economics from the University of Chicago in 1938. His teaching experience began in 1936 at Iowa State College where he taught until 1938. He spent much of World War II at Columbia University, performing mathematical and statistical research for the Manhattan Project. He then spent one year at Brown University. He served on the Columbia faculty from 1947 to 1958.

Stigler was a founding member of the Mont Pelerin Society, and was president from 1976 to 1978.

He also received National Medal of Science in 1987.

Notes

  1. ^ George J. Stigler (1961). “The Economics of Information,” Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), pp. 213-225 (press +).
  2. ^ a b Milton Friedman (1992). "George Joseph Stigler January 17, 1911—December 1, 1991," Biographical Memoirs. National Academy of Sciences.
  3. ^ George J. Stigler (1962a). "Information in the Labor Market." Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), Part 2, Oct., p p. 94-105.
  4. ^ George J. Stigler, 1973. "A Sketch of the History of Truth in Teaching," Journal of Political Economy, 81(2, Part 1), p p. 491-495.

Bibliography

  • ([1941] 1994. Production and Distribution Theories: The Formative Period. New York: Macmillan. Preview.
  • (1961). “The Economics of Information,” Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), pp. 213-225 (press +).
  • (1962a). "Information in the Labor Market." Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), Part 2, p p. 94-105.
  • (1962b). The Intellectual and the Marketplace. Selected Papers, no. 3. Chicago: University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. Reprinted in Sigler (1986), pp. 79-88.
  • (1963). (With Paul Samuelson) "A Dialogue on the Proper Economic Role of the State." Selected Papers, no.7., pp. 3-20. Chicago: University of Chicago Graduate School of Business.
  • (1963). Capital and Rates of Return in Manufacturing Industries. National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
  • (1965). Essays in the History of Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • (1970). (With J.K. Kindahl) The Behavior of Industrial Prices. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York: Columbia University Press.
  • (1971). "The Theory of Economic Regulation." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, no. 3,pp. 3–18.
  • (1975). Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation.
  • (1982). "The Process and Progress of Economics," Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December (with bibliography).
  • (1982). The Economist as Preacher, and Other Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
  • (1983). The Organization of Industry.
  • (1985). Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, autobiography.
  • (1986). The Essence of Stigler, K.R. Leube and T.G. Moore, ed. Scroll or page-arrow to respective essays. ISBN 0-8179-8462-3
  • (1987). The Theory of Price, Fourth Edition. New York: Macmillan.
  • (1988), ed. Chicago Studies in Political Economy.

See also

References

  • Diamond, Arthur M., Jr. (2005). "Measurement, Incentives, and Constraints in Stigler's Economics of Science." The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 12, no. 4637–63.
  • Freedman, Craig (2003). "Do Great Economists Make Great Teachers? George Stigler as a Dissertation Supervisor," Journal of Economic Education,34(3), pp. 282–290 (press +.
  • Friedman, Milton (1993). "George Stigler: A Personal Reminiscence," Journal of Political Economy 101(5) p p. 768–773.
  • _____ (1998). "George J. Stigler, 1911–1991." Biographical Memoirs, National Academy of Sciences press,online, with bibliography.
  • Hammond, J. Daniel, and Claire H. Hammond, ed. (2006). Making Chicago Price Theory: Friedman–Stigler Correspondence, 1945–1957. Routledge. 165 pp. ISBN 0-415-70078-7.
  • Levy, David M., and Sandra J. Peart. (2008). "Stigler, George Joseph (1911–1991)." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
  • The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (1987):
"Stigler, George Joseph" by Peter Newman, v. 4, p. 498.
"Stigler as an historian of economic thought" by Thomas Sowell, v. 4, pp. 498–99.
"Stigler's contribution to microeconomics and industrial organization," by Richard Schmalensee, v. 4, pp. 499–500

External links

Template:Persondata